Abstract
We return to the traditional theme of the distributive consequences of international prices and trade policies, focusing on economies relatively abundant in natural resources with a large non-tradable-goods sector. Changes in international prices create an aggregate demand effect which impacts on the earnings of factors employed in the non-traded goods sector. We show that, in economies highly specialized in the production of tradable goods and where the import-competing sector is small, under standard assumptions, terms-of- trade shifts have a neutral effect on factor prices and thus lack distributive effects, quite differently from Stolper-Samuelson scenarios. In economies with sizable import-competing sectors and two “urban” productive factors (e.g. skilled and unskilled labor), changes in the terms of trade do induce distributional tensions through two channels: (i) the exogenous shift in the relative price of tradable goods, and (ii) the endogenous displacement of the demand for non-tradables. We illustrate how, according to the structure of the economy, different patterns of income distribution may arise. Next, we analyze the introduction of trade duties. Trade taxes change relative prices between tradable goods as a terms-of-trade shock does, but also introduce an additional demand mechanism, that depends on the use the government gives to the revenues. If the tax revenues are transferred back to the private sector, the resulting reallocation of spending favors those factors used intensively in the production of non-tradables.
Acknowledgment
We would like to thank Daniel Aromi, Sebastian Bauer, Joaquin Endara, Martin Guzman, Pablo Mira, Gustavo Montero, Santiago Cesteros, Guido Zack, and an anonymous referee for their comments and suggestions. The usual caveat applies.
A Appendix
Imports as Production Inputs in the Two-Sector Case
Good M is now not only a consumer product but is also used as an input in the production of goods A and N. The proportional change in intermediate imports after a change in the price of A (with
The supply-demand conditions for primary factors L, T and H are still given by:
The trade balance condition:
Cost-price equations:
It can be seen that these equations are satisfied if:
and:
The change in the price of the exportable good has, as in the case in which there are no intermediate imports, neutral effects on the returns to the domestic factors. However, now factor earnings rise more than in proportion to the price of good A because of the expanded production opportunities created by the relative reduction in the cost of international inputs.
B Appendix
Derivation of the Reduced System involving the Sign of the Determinant in the Three-Goods Case
The supply-demand equations for production factors can be written as follows:
Price equations for A and M:
Trade balance:
Taking into account the assumed consumption demand functions and the supply-demand balance of non-tradable-goods:
The system then reduces to:
or:
leading to:
The determinant of this system is:
It can be seen that the only negative term is a multiple of θHMθLAλHNχA. Collecting the terms in λHN:
This reduces to:
But:
And a similar expression for χA.
Then:
Therefore, Ω is unambiguously positive.
C Appendix
Proof of Proposition 4 and Related Results
Proof that
Using the reduced system shown in Appendix B, it follows that:
Proof that
This result is equivalent to
which implies:
because (λLA+λLNχA)θLA+θTA < 1
Expression for
The system can be rearranged (taking into account that
In a similar fashion to what was done before, it can be shown that the determinant of this system is positive:
Then:
Which can be reduced to an expression with an ambiguous sign:
Limit cases
1. Sector A labor intensive: θLA ≈ 1
In the limit:
The value of spending on good N (in terms of M) and the volume consumption of M may increase or fall depending on the parameters. To clarify this, it is useful to rewrite the system as:
The determinant Ω″ can be shown to be positive. Now:
Recalling the expressions for χA, χM:
So that the sign of
2. Sector A, with very low labor intensity: θLA ≈ 0, λLA ≈ 0
Now,
The system can be written:
The determinant Ω´´´ is positive. Now,
Or:
Then,
It can also be shown that:
That is so because:
Also:
It can also be seen that:
and:
D Appendix
Effects of the tax refund in the three-goods case
Recalling equations (34) and (35), the system that determines the effect of the trade tax and refund policy can be written as:
Thus, the change of the endogenous variables
where Ω is the positive determinant. Similar expressions can be found for variables like
It can also be verified that
The only positive term is proportional to θHMθLAλHN. Comparing the analogous terms and remembering the expressions for χA, χM
Also:
References
Acemoglu, D 2002. “Technical Change, Inequality and Labor Market.” Journal of Economic Literature 40: 7–72.10.1257/jel.40.1.7Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D 2003. “Patterns of Skill Premia.” Review of Economic Studies 70: 199–230.10.1111/1467-937X.00242Search in Google Scholar
Beladi, H., and R. Batra. 2004. “Traded and Nontraded Goods and Real Wages.” Review of Development Economics 8 (1): 1–14.10.1111/j.1467-9361.2004.00216.xSearch in Google Scholar
Beladi, H., and R. Oladi. 2009. “Market Interconnection and Wages.” Economic Letters 105: 117–119.10.1016/j.econlet.2009.06.014Search in Google Scholar
Cassing, J. 1977. “International Trade in the Presence of Pure Monopoly in the Non-Traded Goods Sector.” The Economic Journal 87 (347): 523–532.10.2307/2231557Search in Google Scholar
Cassing, J. 1978. “Transport Costs in International Trade Theory: A Comparison with the Analysis of Nontraded Goods.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics XCII (4): 535–550.10.2307/1883174Search in Google Scholar
Coble, D., and N. Magud. 2010. “A Note on Terms of Trade Shocks and the Wage Gap.”.IMF Working Paper, 10/279. Washington: International Monetary Fund.10.5089/9781455210862.001Search in Google Scholar
Deardorff, A., and P. Courant. 1990. “On the Likelihood of Factor Price Equalization with Non-Traded Goods.” International Economic Review 31 (3): 589–596.10.2307/2527163Search in Google Scholar
Diaz Alejandro, C. 1965. Exchange Rate Devaluation in a Semi-Industrialized Economy: The Experience of Argentina, 1955–1961. Cambridge: The MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Ethier, W. 1972. “Nontraded Goods and the Heckscher-Ohlin Model.” International Economic Review 13 (1): 132–147.10.2307/2525910Search in Google Scholar
Ethier, W. 1984. “Higher Dimensional Issues in Trade Theory, chapter 3.”. In Handbook of International Economics. , edited by Jones, R. W., and P. B. Kenen, (Eds.) Vol. 1. Amsterdam: North-Holland.10.1016/S1573-4404(84)01006-6Search in Google Scholar
Galiani, S., D. Heymann, C. Dabus, and F. Tohme. 2008. “On the Emergence of Public Education in Land-Rich Economies.” Journal of Development Economics 86: 434–446.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.12.004Search in Google Scholar
Galiani, S., N. Schofield, and G. Torrens. 2014. “Factor Endowments, Democracy and Trade Policy Convergence.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 16: 119–156.10.1111/jpet.12057Search in Google Scholar
Goldberg, K., and N. Pavcnik. 2007. “Distributional effects of globalization in developing countries.” Journal of economic Literature 45: 39–82.10.1257/jel.45.1.39Search in Google Scholar
Goldberg, K., and N. Pavcnik. 2016. “The Effects of Trade Policy.”.NBER Working Paper 21957. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w21957Search in Google Scholar
Gylfason, T. 2008. “Dutch Disease.”. In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. , edited by Durlauf, S., and L. Blume (Eds.) : McMillan.10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1978-1Search in Google Scholar
Hermida, A., 2015. Skill Premium y Tipo de Cambio Real: El Caso de las Economías Latinoamericanas.Documento de Trabajo CEDLAS.Search in Google Scholar
Johnson, H. G. 1957. “Factor Endowments, International Trade and Factor Prices.” Manchester School 25 (3): 270–283.10.1111/j.1467-9957.1957.tb01000.xSearch in Google Scholar
Jones, R. W. 1974. “Trade with Non-Traded Goods: The Anatomy of Interconnected Markets.” Economica 41: 121–138.10.2307/2553762Search in Google Scholar
Komiya, R. 1967. “Non-Traded Goods and the Pure Theory of International Trade.” International Economic Review 8 (2): 132–152.10.2307/2525597Search in Google Scholar
McDougall, I. 1970. “Non-Traded Goods and the Pure Theory of International Trade.”. In Studies in International Trade. , edited by McDougall, I., and R. N. Snape (Eds.) Amsterdam: North Holland.Search in Google Scholar
O’Rourke, K., and A. Taylor. 2006. “Democracy and Protectionism.”.NBER Working Paper 12250. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.Search in Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. 1999. “Where Did All the Growth Go? External Shocks, Social Conflict and Growth Collapses.” Journal of Economic Growth 4: 385–412.10.1023/A:1009863208706Search in Google Scholar
Rogowski, R. 1989. Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9780691219431Search in Google Scholar
Salter, W. 1959. “Internal and External Balance. The Role of Price and Expenditure Effects.” Economic Record 36: 226–238.10.1111/j.1475-4932.1959.tb00462.xSearch in Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J.E. 2002. Globalization and its Discontents. Vol. 500 Norton.Search in Google Scholar
Stolper, W., and P. A. Samuelson. 1941. “Protection and Real Wages.” Review of Economic Studies 9: 58–73.10.2307/2967638Search in Google Scholar
Swan, T. 1960. “Economic Control in a Dependent Economy.” Economic Record 36: 51–66.10.1111/j.1475-4932.1960.tb00493.xSearch in Google Scholar
Thierfelder, K., and S. Robinson. 2002. “Trade and Tradability: Exports Imports and Factor Markets in the Stolper-Samuelson Model.”.TMD Discussion Paper No. 93.Search in Google Scholar
Williamson, J. 2011. Trade and Poverty: When the Third World Fell Behind. Cambridge: The MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/9780262015158.001.0001Search in Google Scholar
©2017 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Income Distribution, Factor Endowments, and Trade Revisited: The Role of Non-Tradable Goods
- Indirect Tax Reform in Developing Countries: A Consumption-Neutral Approach
- Sensitivity of Purchasing Power Parity Estimates to Estimation Procedures and their Effect on Living Standards Comparisons
- To Pay or Not to Pay? Evaluating the Belgian Law Against Vulture Funds
- New Approaches to Identifying State Fragility
Articles in the same Issue
- Income Distribution, Factor Endowments, and Trade Revisited: The Role of Non-Tradable Goods
- Indirect Tax Reform in Developing Countries: A Consumption-Neutral Approach
- Sensitivity of Purchasing Power Parity Estimates to Estimation Procedures and their Effect on Living Standards Comparisons
- To Pay or Not to Pay? Evaluating the Belgian Law Against Vulture Funds
- New Approaches to Identifying State Fragility