Home An intuitive skewness-based symmetry test applicable to stationary time series data
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

An intuitive skewness-based symmetry test applicable to stationary time series data

  • Luke Hartigan ORCID logo EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: March 15, 2019

Abstract

I propose a simple skewness-based test of symmetry suitable for a stationary time series. The test is based on the difference between the squared deviation of a process above its median with that below it. The test has many attractive features: it is applicable to weakly dependent processes, it has a familiar form, it can be implemented using regression, and it has a standard Gaussian limiting distribution under the null hypothesis of symmetry. The finite sample properties of the test statistic are examined via Monte Carlo simulation and suggest that it has better size-adjusted power compared to competing tests in the literature when examining moderately persistence processes. I apply the test to a range of US economic and financial data and find stronger support for asymmetry in financial series compared to economic series.

Acknowledgement

This paper is based on the fourth chapter of my Ph.D. dissertation. I am grateful to Yunjong Eo, Jiti Gao, James Morley, Timothy Neal, and Philip Rothman as well as the editor Bruce Mizrach and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions which greatly improved the quality of this paper. I also thank William Dunsmuir for useful comments on preliminary work related to this paper. All remaining errors are solely my own.

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

The proof of Proposition 1 follows Feunou, Jahan-Parvar, and Tédongap (2016) very closely with a few small changes.

P1: For any a > 0 and b, the median of axt + b is equal to am + b. The upside squared deviation of axt + b is given by:

E[(axt+bE[axt+baxt+bam+b])2axt+bam+b]=a2σu2

which holds because:

a2σu2=a2E[(xtE[xtxtm])2xtm]=E[(axtE[axtxtm])2xtm]=E[(axt+bE[axt+bxtm])2xtm]=E[(axt+bE[axt+baxt+bam+b])2axt+bam+b]

Similarly, the downside squared deviation of axt + b is given by:

E[(axt+bE[axt+baxt+b<am+b])2axt+b<am+b]=a2σd2

which holds since:

a2σd2=a2E[(xtE[xtxt<m])2xt<m]=E[(axtE[axtxt<m])2xt<m]=E[(axt+bE[axt+bxt<m])2xt<m]=E[(axt+bE[axt+baxt+b<am+b])2axt+b<am+b]

Hence, the skewness-based measure of symmetry for axt + b is given by:

δ(axt+b)=a2σu2a2σd2=a2(σu2σd2)=a2δ

Which satisfies P1 up to a multiplicative constant (this is similar to Feunou, Jahan-Parvar and Tédongap, 2016, see footnote 5 on page 1266).

P2: Suppose that xt is from a symmetric and unimodal distribution, then we know that the median is equal to the mean for the distribution.

As a result, xtm is symmetric and unimodal with zero mean. As a consequence, xtm and its opposite, mxt have the same distribution. The upside squared deviation of xtm is equal to σu2 and the downside squared deviation of xtm is equal to σd2. However:

σd2=E[(xtmE[xtmxtm<0])2xtm<0]=E[(mxtE[mxtxtm<0])2xtm<0]=E[(mxtE[mxtmxt<0])2mxt<0]

So, σd2 is also the upside squared deviation of mxt. Hence xtm and mxt have the same distribution, which means σu2=σd2 and as a result δ(xt)=0. This shows that the skewness-based measure of symmetry satisfies P2.

P3: Note that the median of −xt is just −m. The upside squared deviation of −xt is therefore the downside squared deviation of xt:

E[(xtE[xtxtm])2xtm]=E[(xtE[xtxtm])2xtm]=E[(xtE[xtxt<m])2xt<m]=σd2

By the same reasoning it can be shown that the downside squared deviation of −xt is equal to σu2, the upside squared deviation of xt. As a result, we have:

δ(xt)=E[(xtE[xtxtm])2xtm]E[(xtE[xtxt<m])2xt<m]=σd2σu2=σu2σd2=δ(xt)

Hence, the skewness-based measure of symmetry satisfies P3.

Proof of Proposition 2

The proof of Proposition 2 closely follows the logic of the proof of Theorem 4 from Giacomini and White (2006). I separately show that under ℍ0, N(δ¯/σδ)dN(0,σδ2), where σδ2=var[Nδ¯] and that σ^δσδp0, from which the result follows.

The variable σδ2 is finite by (ii) and it is positive for all N sufficiently large by (iii). By writing N(δ¯/σδ)=N1/2n=1Nσδ1δ^n, it can be shown that the sequence {σδ1δ^n} satisfies the conditions of Wooldridge and White (1988)’s Central Limit Theorem for mixing processes. First, {σδ1δ^n} is mixing of the same size as xt. Furthermore, by (ii) E|σδ1δ^n|2+ϵ< for some small ϵ > 0. Hence, {σδ1δ^n} satisfies the conditions of Corollary 3.1 of Wooldridge and White (1988), which implies that N(σδ1δ¯)dN(0,σδ2).

Based on a similar line of reasoning, {δ^n} is mixing of the same size as xt which implies that {δ^n} is also mixing with ϕ of size r/(r1) or α of size 2r/(r2). This, together with assumption (ii) and with the fact that E[δ^n]=0 under ℍ0, implies that the conditions of Theorem 6.20 of White (2000) are satisfied, and therefore σ^δσδp0.

References

Anatolyev, S., and A. Petukhov. 2016. “Uncovering the Skewness News Impact Curve.” Journal of Financial Econometrics 14: 746–771.10.1093/jjfinec/nbw005Search in Google Scholar

Andrews, D. W. K. 1991. “Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation.” Econometrica 59: 817–858.10.2307/2938229Search in Google Scholar

Andrews, D. W. K., and J. C. Monahan. 1992. “An Improved Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator.” Econometrica 60: 953–966.10.2307/2951574Search in Google Scholar

Bai, J., and S. Ng. 2001. “A Consistent Test for Conditional Symmetry in Time Series Models.” Journal of Econometrics 103: 225–258.10.1016/S0304-4076(01)00044-6Search in Google Scholar

Bai, J., and S. Ng. 2005. “Tests for Skewness, Kurtosis, and Normality for Time Series Data.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 23: 49–60.10.1198/073500104000000271Search in Google Scholar

Barndorff-Neilsen, O. E., S. Kinnebrouk, and N. Shephard. 2010. “Measuring Downside Risk: Realised Semivariance.” In Volatility and Time Series Econometrics: Essays in Honor of Robert F. Engle, edited by T. Bollerslev, J. Russell, and M. Watson, 117–136. Oxford University Press.10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199549498.003.0007Search in Google Scholar

Bontemps, C., and N. Meddahi. 2005. “Testing Normality: A GMM Approach.” Journal of Econometrics 124: 149–186.10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.014Search in Google Scholar

Brown, M. B., and A. B. Forsythe. 1974. “Robust Tests for the Equality of Variances.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 69: 364–367.10.1080/01621459.1974.10482955Search in Google Scholar

Casella, G., and R. L. Berger. 2002. Statistical Inference. 2nd ed. Pacific Gove, CA: Duxbury/Thomson Learning.Search in Google Scholar

Davis, C. 2015. sgt: Skewed Generalized T Distribution Tree. URL https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=sgt, R package version 2.0.Search in Google Scholar

DeLong, J. B., and L. H. Summers. 1984. “Are Business Cycles Symmetric?” Working Paper 1444, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1050 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA 02138. URL http://www.nber.org/papers/w1444.10.3386/w1444Search in Google Scholar

den Haan, W. J., and A. T. Levin. 1997. “A Practitioner’s Guide to Robust Covariance Matrix Estimation, chapter 12.” In Handbook of Statistics, Robust Inference, edited by G. S. Maddala and C. R. Rao, volume 15, chapter 12, 299–342. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/S0169-7161(97)15014-3Search in Google Scholar

Feunou, B., M. R. Jahan-Parvar, and R. Tédongap. 2013. “Modeling Market Downside Volatility.” Review of Finance 17: 443–481.10.1093/rof/rfr024Search in Google Scholar

Feunou, B., M. R. Jahan-Parvar, and R. Tédongap. 2016. “Which Parametric Model for Conditional Skewness?” The European Journal of Finance 22: 1237–1271.10.1080/1351847X.2013.877515Search in Google Scholar

Feunou, B., M. R. Jahan-Parvar, and C. Okou. 2017. “Downside Variance Risk Premium.” Journal of Financial Econometrics. Invited Paper, 1–43.10.1093/jjfinec/nbx020Search in Google Scholar

Giacomini, R., and H. White. 2006. “Tests of Conditional Predictive Ability.” Econometrica 74: 1545–1578.10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00718.xSearch in Google Scholar

Groeneveld, R. A., and G. Meeden. 1984. “Measuring Skewness and Kurtosis.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series D (The Statistician) 33: 391–399.10.2307/2987742Search in Google Scholar

Hansen, B. E. 1994. “Autoregressive Conditional Density Estimation.” International Economic Review 35: 705–730.10.2307/2527081Search in Google Scholar

Hansen, C., J. B. McDonald, and W. K. Newey. 2010. “Instrumental Variables Estimation with Flexible Distributions.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 28: 13–25.10.1920/wp.cem.2007.2107Search in Google Scholar

Hartigan, L. 2018. “Alternative HAC Covariance Matrix Estimators with Improved Finite Sample Properties.” Computational Statistics & Data Analysis 119: 55–73.10.1016/j.csda.2017.09.007Search in Google Scholar

Harvey, C. R., and A. Siddique. 1999. “Autoregressive Conditional Skewness.” The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 34: 465–487.10.2307/2676230Search in Google Scholar

Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Search in Google Scholar

Kim, J.-R., S. Mittnik, and S. T. Rachev. 1996. “Detecting Asymmetries in Observed Linear Time Series and Unobserved Disturbances.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics 1: 131–143.10.2202/1558-3708.1017Search in Google Scholar

Kim, T.-H., and H. White. 2004. “On More Robust Estimation of Skewness and Kurtosis.” Finance Research Letters 1: 56–73.10.1016/S1544-6123(03)00003-5Search in Google Scholar

Levene, H. 1960. “Robust Tests for Equality of Variance, chapter 25.” In Contributions to Probability and Statistics: Essays in Honor of Harold Hotelling, edited by I. Olkin, S. G. Ghurye, W. Hoeffding, W. G. Madow, and H. B. Mann, 278–292. Standford, CA: Stanford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Lloyd, C. J. 2005. “Estimating Test Power Adjustment for Size.” Journal of Statistical Computation and Simulation 75: 921–934.10.1080/00949650412331321160Search in Google Scholar

McDonald, J. B., and W. K. Newey. 1988. “Partially Adaptive Estimation of Regression Models via the Generalized T Distribution.” Econometric Theory 4: 428–457.10.1017/S0266466600013384Search in Google Scholar

Mitchell, W. C. 1927. Business Cycles: The Problem and Its Setting. Number 10 in Publications of the National Bureau of Economic Research, New York: NBER.Search in Google Scholar

Newey, W. K., and K. D. West. 1987. “A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix.” Econometrica 55: 703–708.10.2307/1913610Search in Google Scholar

Pearson, K. 1895. “Contributions to the Mathematical Theory of Evolution. II. Skew Variation in Homogeneous Material.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences 186: 343–414.10.1098/rsta.1895.0010Search in Google Scholar

Premaratne, G., and A. Bera. 2005. “A Test for Symmetry with Leptokutic Financial Data.” Journal of Financial Econometrics 3: 169–187.10.1093/jjfinec/nbi009Search in Google Scholar

Psaradakis, Z., and M. Vávra. 2015. “A Quantile-Based Test for Symmetry of Weakly Dependent Processes.” Journal of Time Series Analysis 36: 587–598.10.1111/jtsa.12132Search in Google Scholar

Ramberg, J. S., and B. W. Schmeiser. 1974. “An Approximate Method for Generating Asymmetric Random Variables.” Communications of the ACM 17: 78–82.10.1145/360827.360840Search in Google Scholar

Ramsey, J. B., and P. Rothman. 1996. “Time Irreversibility and Business Cycle Asymmetry.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 28: 1–21.10.2307/2077963Search in Google Scholar

Randles, R. H., M. A. Fligner, G. E. Policello II, and D. A. Wolfe. 1980. “An Asymmetrically Distribtuion-Free Test for Symmetry Versus Asymmetry.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 75: 168–172.10.1080/01621459.1980.10477448Search in Google Scholar

Sanderson, C., and R. Curtin. 2016. “Armadillo: A Template-based C++ Library for Linear Algebra.” Journal of Open Source Software 1: 26–32.10.21105/joss.00026Search in Google Scholar

Sichel, D. E. 1993. “Business Cycle Asymmetry: A Deeper Look.” Economic Inquiry 31: 224–236.10.1111/j.1465-7295.1993.tb00879.xSearch in Google Scholar

Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson. 1988. “A Probability Model of the Coincident Economic Indicators.” Working Paper 2772, National Bureau of Economic Research, URL http://www.nber.org/papers/w2772.10.3386/w2772Search in Google Scholar

Theodossiou, P. 1998. “Financial Data and the Skewed Generalized T Distribution.” Management Science 44: 1650–1661.10.1287/mnsc.44.12.1650Search in Google Scholar

White, H. 2000. Asymptotic Theory for Econometricians. 2nd rev. ed. Bingley, UK: Emerald Publishing Limited.Search in Google Scholar

Wooldridge, J., and H. White. 1988. “Some Invariance Principles and Central Limit Theorems for Dependent Heterogeneous Processes.” Econometric Theory 4: 210–230.10.1017/S0266466600012032Search in Google Scholar


Supplementary Material

The online version of this article offers supplementary material (DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/snde-2017-0031).


Published Online: 2019-03-15

©2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 11.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/snde-2017-0031/html
Scroll to top button