Abstract
When firms advertise a vertically differentiated product attribute, they increase the weight consumers put on that attribute. This creates a spillover effect as one firm’s advertising can increase demand for other firms that also have the attribute. I develop a market share attraction model and find that as spillover increases, firms advertise less. Profit can be increasing or decreasing in spillover depending on the particular industry environment. Spillover lends a “public good” quality to advertising and firms free-ride in equilibrium. An advertising ban has an ambiguous effect on the profits of firms with the attribute, but always increases profits of firms without the attribute.
Acknowledgments
This paper benefited greatly from helpful comments by the editor and anonymous referees.
Appendix
A Existence of Equilibrium
Consider a general attraction model
where f(s) denotes a firm’s attraction as a function of the level of its own advertising s and g(s) denotes the sum of all other firms’ attractions which may depend on the original firm’s advertising. It is assumed that
Note that even in the general case, the marginal benefit of advertising is decreasing in market share. This is therefore a feature of all attraction models and not specific to the case of linear attraction functions.
The second derivative is given by
For a firm advertising in equilibrium,
The problem of existence of Nash equilibrium for attraction function models is not entirely due to the spillover effect. Gruca and Sudharshan (1991) have pointed out the non-existence of equilibrium for the logit model in advertising settings. Mesak and Means (1998) show that if
B Proofs
B.1 Proposition 4
First, I show that if the total level of advertising increases (decreases) in equilibrium, then the each firm’s individual level also increases (decreases). Let s* denote the total level of advertising. By assumption, a small change in a parameter does not result in the set of advertisers changing. If s* increases, then it must be the case that at least one firm i of the L advertisers increased its advertising. All else equal, this increases the market share of firm i. But in equilibrium, all advertisers have the same market share, so firm i’s increase must result in increases by all remaining advertisers. Therefore, I can do comparative statics on the aggregate level of advertising s*, and individual comparative statics must have the same sign.
The aggregate amount of advertising in equilibrium can be implicitly defined by adding up the L first-order conditions of the advertising firms:
where xN is the sum of all firms’ x attributes and xL is the sum of the advertising firms’ x attributes. I then use the implicit function theorem to do comparative statics on s* with respect to the exogenous variable of interest.
The numerator is clearly positive, and the denominator is positive as
Both the numerator and denominator are positive, therefore
B.2 Proposition 5
Following Theorem 1 in Caputo (1996), the envelope results for the model are given by the following. Suppose firm i has
and
The sign of the second line is indeterminate, as
Now suppose firm i has
Suppose firm i has
References
Aruoba, S. B., and J. Fernández-Villaverde. 2014. “A Comparison of Programming Languages in Economics.” Working Paper 20263, National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber. org/papers/w20263.Search in Google Scholar
Bagwell, K.. 2007. “The Economic Analysis of Advertising.” Handbook of Industrial Organization 3:1701–844.10.1016/S1573-448X(06)03028-7Search in Google Scholar
Bass, F. M., A. Krishnamoorthy, A. Prasad, and S. P. Sethi. 2005. “Generic and Brand Advertising Strategies in a Dynamic Duopoly.” Marketing Science 24 (4):556–68. doi:10.1287/mksc.1050.0119.Search in Google Scholar
Bezanson, J., S. Karpinski, V. B. Shah, and A. Edelman. 2012. “Julia: A Fast Dynamic Language for Technical Computing.” CoRR. abs/1209.5145.Search in Google Scholar
Bloch, F., and D. Manceau. 1999. “Persuasive Advertising in Hotelling’s Model of Product Differentiation.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 17 (4):557–74. ISSN 0167–7187. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0167-7187(98)00014-9.Search in Google Scholar
Caputo, M. R.. 1996. “The Envelope Theorem and Comparative Statics of Nash Equilibria.” Games and Economic Behavior 13 (2):201–24. ISSN 0899–8256. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/game.1996.0034.Search in Google Scholar
Carey, C., and D. Bolton. 1996. “Brand Versus Generic Advertising and the Decision to Advertise Collectively.” Review of Industrial Organization 11 (1):93–105. ISSN 0889-938X. doi:10.1007/BF00163600.Search in Google Scholar
Dearden, J., and G. Lilien. 2001. “Advertising Competition: Who Pays? Who Gains?” In Advertising and Differentiated Products, Volume 10 of Advances in Applied Microeconomics, edited byM. Baye and J. Nelson. Oxford, UK: Elsevier Science.Search in Google Scholar
Gruca, T. S., and D. Sudharshan. 1991. “Equilibrium Characteristics of Multinomial Logit Market Share Models.” Journal of Marketing Research 28 (4):480–2.10.1177/002224379102800410Search in Google Scholar
Karnani, A.. 1985. “Strategic Implications of Market Share Attraction Models.” Management Science 31 (5):536–47.10.1287/mnsc.31.5.536Search in Google Scholar
Kosin, I., K. Yasushi, and T. V. J. Generic. 2009. “Advertising in Markets with Informative Brand Advertising.” Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization 7 (1):1–22.Search in Google Scholar
Krishnamurthy, S.. 2000. “Enlarging the Pie Vs. Increasing One’s Slice: An Analysis of the Relationship Between Generic and Brand Advertising.” Marketing Letters 11 (1):37–48. ISSN 0923–0645. doi:10.1023/A:1008146709712.Search in Google Scholar
Mesak, H. I., and T. L. Means. 1998. “Modelling Advertising Budgeting and Allocation Decisions Using Modified Multinomial Logit Market Share Models.” Journal of the Operations Research Society 49:1260–9.10.1057/palgrave.jors.2600647Search in Google Scholar
Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts. 1986. “Price and Advertising Signals of Product Quality.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (4):796–821.10.1086/261408Search in Google Scholar
Piga, C.. 1998. “A Dynamic Model of Advertising and Product Differentiation.” Review of Industrial Organization 13 (5):509–22. ISSN 0889-938X. doi:10.1023/A:1007743111299.Search in Google Scholar
Seldon, B., and K. Doroodian. 1990. “Does Purely Predatory Advertising Exist?” Review of Industrial Organization 5 (3):45–70. ISSN 0889-938X. doi:10.1007/BF02229586.Search in Google Scholar
Sherer, F. M.. 1970. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Rand McNally College Publishing Co.Search in Google Scholar
Tremblay, V. J., and C. Martins-Filho. 2001. “A Model of Vertical Differentiation, Brand Loyalty, and Persuasive Advertising.” In Advertising and Differentiated Products, Volume 10 of Advances in Applied Microeconomics, edited by M. Baye and J. Nelson, 221–38. Elsevier Science.10.1016/S0278-0984(01)10011-8Search in Google Scholar
Tremblay, V., and S. Polasky. 2002. “Advertising with Subjective Horizontal and Vertical Product Differentiation.” Review of Industrial Organization 20 (3):253–65. ISSN 0889-938X. doi:10.1023/A:1015095508749.Search in Google Scholar
von der Fehr, N. -H. M., and K. Stevik. 1998. “Persuasive Advertising and Product Differentiation.” Southern Economic Journal 65 (1):113–26.10.2307/1061355Search in Google Scholar
©2016 by De Gruyter