Home Co-Investments and Tacit Collusion in Regulated Network Industries: Experimental Evidence
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Co-Investments and Tacit Collusion in Regulated Network Industries: Experimental Evidence

  • Jan Krämer EMAIL logo and Ingo Vogelsang
Published/Copyright: April 19, 2017

Abstract

Several regulatory authorities have recently allowed competing network operators to co-invest in network infrastructure. With the use of a laboratory experiment, we investigate the impact of co-investments on competition in regulated network industries, particularly in comparison to unilateral and duplicate investments. Our main finding is that co-investment (i.e. cooperation at the infrastructure level) facilitates tacit collusion (i.e. cooperation at the retail level) significantly, which questions the positive evaluation of co-investments with respect to consumers’ surplus in the theoretical literature.

JEL Classification: C92; D22; L13; L51; L97

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Niklas Horstmann for indispensable research assistance as well as two insightful referees and Marc Bourreau, Carlo Cambini, Steffen Hoernig and participants of the European Conference of the International Telecommunications Society (ITS), the Conference of the German Association of Experimental Economics (GfEW) and the Conference of the European Association of Research in Industrial Economics (EARIE) for valuable comments. Financial support from Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG) through GRK 895 is gratefully acknowledged.

Appendix

A Proofs for the Equilibria of the Network Competition Game

In the following, we investigate the equilibrium outcome of the above model with respect to firms’ (i) coverage and (ii) prices under the three different regulatory scenarios.

Retail equilibrium. First, consider the strategic interaction in the retail phase, given the firms’ decisions from the investment phase. In fact, because the firms’ investments in network infrastructure are sunk, these costs are relevant only insofar in the retail phase as they determine the access charge that firms have to pay each other. The access charge, however, may lead to positive marginal costs for the access seeker. A firm’s average marginal costs are important for the price level in the retail phase because they determine a lower bound on prices. More formally, it can be shown that (7) constitutes the unique price equilibrium (neglecting increments), because no firm wants to unilaterally deviate from this price:

  1. No firm would like to raise its price above pt, say to pt+ϵ: In this case it would lose all demand for its retail product and receive payoffs from wholesale access only, such that its profit is

    Πi,t+ϵ=n¯cj.

    It is easy to see that Πi,t>Πi,t+ϵpt>ci+cj, which is satisfied by (7).

  2. No firm wants to lower its price below pt, say to ptϵ: In this case it would receive the full market demand (n̅), but at the same time lose all profits from wholesale, i.e.

    Πi,tϵ=n¯(ptϵci).

    It follows that Πi,t>Πi,tϵpt<ci+cj+ϵ/δi, which is also satisfied by (7) since 0<δi <1.

Moreover, as the stage game otherwise parallels a standard Bertrand game, it is easy to see that this Nash equilibrium must be unique. Furthermore, Farrell and Maskin (1989) show that p=(p1,,pt,,pT) is the unique weakly renegotiation proof (WRP) equilibrium of the repeated Bertrand game. It is also the unique subgame perfect equilibrium (Selten 1975).[12] Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that in equilibrium both firms will price their retail product at pi,t=ptv and receive a demand of Di,t=n¯δi. Hence, a firm’s equilibrium profit is

(A.1)Πi,t=n¯δi(ptcicj)+n¯cj.

Investment equilibrium. For the derivation of the investment equilibrium, we refer to the working paper version of this article (Krämer and Vogelsang 2016). However, we wish to highlight here that neither duplication nor co-investment is an equilibrium outcome when equilibrium prices are expected. This is consistent with other, more complex models on this issue (see Bourreau et al. 2013). Although the co-investing firms can save some infrastructure investment costs, the resulting competition on the common infrastructure will usually drive retail profits down to an even larger extent. For example, in a co-investment duopoly each firm will have to bear more than 50% of the investment cost of a monopoly firm due to some individual fixed costs, wheras each firm receives less than 50% of the monopoly profit due to the emergence of competition. Thus, co-investment does not emerge in equilibrium unless there exist some additional effects, which we do not model here, like an additional demand expansion effect due to co-investment or an actual cost reduction effect, e.g. due to lower financing costs (Bourreau et al. 2013).

B Panel Analysis of Tacit Collusion

In addition to the OLS regression reported in Table 5, we also consider the following three-level mixed effects model, which accepts measurements at the level of a single retail period (t), and thus allows us to analyze tacit collusion not only across rounds, but also across periods within rounds:

(B.1)Pricetds=β0+(β1+βs)Round+(β2+βds)Period+β3RoundPeriod+iβiRemaining Covariates+ζs+ζds+ϵtds

Here, pricetds denotes the (deviation of the) price (from the equilibrium price or average costs) in period t for duopoly d in the independent subgroup s. ζs and βs are random effects that are common to observations from the same subgroup s. ζds as well as βds are random effects common to the measurements from the same duopoly d, nested in subgroup s.

Table B.1:

Multilevel Mixed-Effect Panel Regressions on Tacit Collusion.

(1)

ΔEQ
(2)

ΔAC
(3)

Market price
(4)

Own price
Duplication (10K HH)1.534**−1.681***−0.119−1.605***
(0.467)(0.472)(0.472)(0.407)
Co-investment (10K HH)3.652***1.744***1.443***−0.350
(0.333)(0.338)(0.431)(0.326)
Coverage (10K HH)2.237***2.100***0.975*0.0749
(0.442)(0.446)(0.425)(0.402)
Communication1.010−0.1741.8351.706
(1.884)(1.943)(1.953)(2.212)
Round2.504***2.155**1.964***1.233*
(0.649)(0.677)(0.585)(0.586)
Period−0.532*−0.822***−0.532*−0.822***
(0.250)(0.245)(0.250)(0.245)
Period×time−0.03350.0380−0.03350.0380
(0.0911)(0.0893)(0.0911)(0.0893)
Equilibrium price0.516***
(0.0688)
Average costs0.176***
(0.0429)
Constant−9.243**−2.50712.43**32.36***
(3.262)(3.339)(4.263)(3.534)
Observations1400280014002800
Log lik.−4539.6−9626.2−4519.6−9458.1
  1. Standard errors in parentheses. +p<0.10, *p<0.05, **p<0.01, ***p<0.001.

  2. The regression confirms the results of the OLS regression in Table 5 and additionally shows that tacit collusion decreases over the periods in a given round. However, there is no significant interaction effect between periods and rounds.

References

BEREC (2012) BEREC Report on Co-investment and Significant Market Power (SMP) in Next Generation Access Networks (NGA). Tech. Rep. BoR(12) 41, Body of European Regulators for Electronic Communications.Search in Google Scholar

Boone, J. (2008) “A New Way to Measure Competition,” The Economic Journal, 118(531):1245–1261.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2008.02168.xSearch in Google Scholar

Bourreau, M., C. Cambini and S. Hoernig (2010) “National FTTH Plans in France, Italy and Portugal,” Communications & Strategies, 1(78):107–126.Search in Google Scholar

Bourreau, M., C. Cambini and S. Hoernig (2012) “Ex Ante Regulation and Co-Investment in the Transition to Next Generation Access,” Telecommunications Policy, 36(5):399–406.10.1016/j.telpol.2011.11.024Search in Google Scholar

Bourreau, M., C. Cambini and S. Hoernig (2013) Cooperative Investment, Uncertainty and Access. CEPR Discussion Papers 9376, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers. http://ideas.repec.org/p/cpr/ceprdp/9376.html.Search in Google Scholar

Briglauer, W., S. Frübing and I. Vogelsang (2014) “The Impact of Alternative Public Policies on The Deployment of New Communications Infrastructure–A Survey,” Review of Network Economics, 13(3):227–270.10.1515/rne-2015-0004Search in Google Scholar

Cabral, L. (2000) “R&D Cooperation and Product Market Competition,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18(7):1033–1047.10.1016/S0167-7187(99)00011-9Search in Google Scholar

Cambini, C. and Y. Jiang (2009) “Broadband Investment and Regulation: A Literature Review,” Telecommunications Policy, 33(10–11):559–574.10.1016/j.telpol.2009.08.007Search in Google Scholar

Cambini, C. and V. Silvestri (2012) “Technology Investment and Alternative Regulatory Regimes with Demand Uncertainty,” Information Economics and Policy, 24(3):212–230.10.1016/j.infoecopol.2012.08.003Search in Google Scholar

Cambini, C. and V. Silvestri (2013) “Investment Sharing in Broadband Networks,” Telecommunications Policy, 37(10):861–878.10.1016/j.telpol.2013.05.010Search in Google Scholar

Cooper, R. W. and T. W. Ross (2009) “Sustaining Cooperation with Joint Ventures,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 25(1):31–54.10.1093/jleo/ewm051Search in Google Scholar

Czernich, N., O. Falck, T. Kretschmer and L. Woessmann (2011) “Broadband Infrastructure and Economic Growth,” The Economic Journal, 121(552):505–532.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2011.02420.xSearch in Google Scholar

DeGraba, P. (2003) “Bottleneck Input Supplier’s Opportunity Cost of Competing Downstream,” Journal of Regulatory Economics, 23(3):287–297.10.1023/A:1023364210896Search in Google Scholar

Duso, T., L.-H. Röller and J. Seldeslachts (2014) “Collusion Through Joint R&D: An Empirical Assessment,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(2):349–370.10.1162/REST_a_00367Search in Google Scholar

Engel, C. (2007) “How Much Collusion? A Meta-Analysis of Oligopoly Experiments,” Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 3(4):491.10.1093/joclec/nhm016Search in Google Scholar

Farrell, J. and E. Maskin (1989) “Renegotiation in Repeated Games,” Games and Economic Behavior, 1(4):327–360.10.1016/0899-8256(89)90021-3Search in Google Scholar

Fischbacher, U. (2007) “z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-Made Economic Experiments,” Experimental Economics, 10(2):171–178.10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4Search in Google Scholar

Fonseca, M. and H. Normann (2012) “Explicit vs. Tacit Collusion–the Impact of Communication in Oligopoly Experiments,” European Economic Review, 56(8):1759–1772.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.09.002Search in Google Scholar

Greiner, B. (2004) “An Online Recruitment System for Economic Experiments.” In: (K. Kremer and V. Macho, eds.) Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen 2003. GWDG Bericht 63. Göttingen: Gesellschaft für wissenschaftliche Datenverarbeitung, pp. 79–93.Search in Google Scholar

Guthrie, G. (2006) “Regulating Infrastructure: The Impact on Risk and Investment,” Journal of Economic Literature, 44(4):925–972.10.1257/jel.44.4.925Search in Google Scholar

Hoernig, S., S. Jay, K. Neumann, M. Peitz, T. Plückebaum and I. Vogelsang (2012) “The Impact of Different Fibre Access Network Technologies on Cost, Competition and Welfare,” Telecommunications Policy, 36(2):96–112.10.1016/j.telpol.2011.12.003Search in Google Scholar

Hoernig, S. H. (2006). “Should Uniform Pricing Constraints be Imposed on Entrants?” Journal of Regulatory Economics, 30(2):199–216.10.1007/s11149-006-0013-6Search in Google Scholar

Horstmann, N. and J. Krämer (2013) “Price Discrimination or Uniform Pricing: Which Colludes More?” Economics Letters, 120(3):379–383.10.1016/j.econlet.2013.05.011Search in Google Scholar

Huck, S., H. Normann and J. Oechssler (2004) “Two are Few and Four are Many: Number Effects in Experimental Oligopolies,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 53(4):435–446.10.1016/j.jebo.2002.10.002Search in Google Scholar

Krämer, J. and I. Vogelsang (2016) Co-investments and Tacit Collusion in Regulated Network Industries: Experimental Evidence. Working paper. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2119927.10.1515/rne-2016-0026Search in Google Scholar

Mason, C. F., O. R. Phillips and C. Nowell (1992) “Duopoly Behavior in Asymmetric Markets: An Experimental Evaluation,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 74(4):662–670.10.2307/2109380Search in Google Scholar

Miyagiwa, K. (2009) “Collusion and Research Joint Ventures,” The Journal of Industrial Economics, 57(4):768–784.10.1111/j.1467-6451.2009.00399.xSearch in Google Scholar

Nicklisch, A. (2012) “Does Collusive Advertising Facilitate Collusive Pricing? Evidence from Experimental Duopolies,” European Journal of Law and Economics, 34(3):515–532.10.1007/s10657-010-9180-0Search in Google Scholar

Nitsche, R. and L. Wiethaus (2010) NGA: Access Regulation, Investment, and Welfare–Model Based Comparative Analysis, ESMT No. WP-110-02.Search in Google Scholar

Nitsche, R. and L. Wiethaus (2011) “Access Regulation and Investment in Next Generation Networks–A Ranking of Regulatory Regimes,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29(2):263–272.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2010.07.002Search in Google Scholar

Normann, H. and R. Ricciuti (2009) “Laboratory Experiments for Economic Policy Making,” Journal of Economic Surveys, 23(3):407–432.10.1111/j.1467-6419.2008.00567.xSearch in Google Scholar

Normann, H.-T., J. Roesch and L. M. Schultz (2015) “Do Buyer Groups Facilitate Collusion?” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 109:72–84.10.1016/j.jebo.2014.11.004Search in Google Scholar

Plott, C. (1987) “Dimensions of Parallelism: Some Policy Applications of Experimental Methods.” In: (Alvin E. Roth, ed.) Laboratory Experimentation in Economics: Six Points of View. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Ch. 7, pp. 193–219.10.1017/CBO9780511528316.007Search in Google Scholar

Potters, J. and S. Suetens (2013) “Oligopoly Experiments in the Current Millenium,” Journal of Economic Surveys, 27(3):439–460.10.1111/joes.12025Search in Google Scholar

Röller, L.-H. and L. Waverman (2001) “Telecommunications Infrastructure and Economic Development: A Simultaneous Approach,” American Economic Review, 91:909–923.10.1257/aer.91.4.909Search in Google Scholar

Selten, R. (1975) “Reexamination of the Perfectness Concept for Equilibrium Points in Extensive Games,” International Journal of Game Theory, 4(1):25–55.10.2307/j.ctv173f1fh.23Search in Google Scholar

Suetens, S. (2008) “Does R&D Cooperation Facilitate Price Collusion? An Experiment,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 66(34):822–836.10.1016/j.jebo.2007.01.002Search in Google Scholar

Suetens, S. and J. Potters (2007) “Bertrand Colludes more than Cournot,” Experimental Economics, 10(1):71–77.10.1007/s10683-006-9132-2Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2017-4-19
Published in Print: 2017-5-24

©2016 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 30.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rne-2016-0026/html
Scroll to top button