Home Vote for Your Family! Particularism, Support for Democracy and Support for Shari’a in the Arab World
Article Publicly Available

Vote for Your Family! Particularism, Support for Democracy and Support for Shari’a in the Arab World

  • Femke E. Bakker and Valentina Rotondi EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: August 12, 2016

Abstract

This paper examines the micro-foundations of the relationship between political particularism, support for democracy and support for Shari’a in the Arab World. Our hypotheses suggest that particularism reduces support for democracy whilst it increases support for Shari’a since, at the individual-level, in-group (family/clan) obligations are more binding than obligations towards the state (universal). We test our hypotheses using data from the Arab Barometer. Results suggest that, even when allowing for the correlation of the error terms, particularism significantly increases support for Shari’a whilst it decreases support for democracy. Our results are robust to alternative specifications of the model and to the use of techniques aimed at addressing the potential endogeneity of particularism.

JEL: Z10; O10; O17

1 Introduction

This paper studies the effects of political particularism on support for democracy and support for Shari’a in the Arab World. The so-called “Arab Spring” has been regarded as a potential new wave of democratization, the rise of the peoples within several Arab countries against oppressive elites breathed the promise of a democratic Middle East. Although multifaceted, with causes and implications specific to each country, these protests were in large part moved by feelings of frustration over poor economic performance and by the refusal of the existing political systems that were perceived as corrupted and non-democratic (de Miguel, Jamal, and Tessler 2015). The question that only the future will answer is whether or not these countries will be able to make the transition towards consolidated democracy. One of the important aspects of getting through such a transition is how the new democratic political system is regarded legitimate by its citizens and how these citizens feel that their values actually “fit” with democracy (Lipset 1960). To put it differently, popular support is considered a crucial issue of regime stability, especially in emerging democracies (Diamond 1999).

Several scholars so far have investigated the determinants of individual-level support for democracy. Recently, part of this literature has underlined the central role played not only by structural factors, such as institutional reform and economic development, but also by political culture (Tessler 2002b). One of the key aspects affecting democratic support and stability is the structure of the electoral system (Svolik 2013; Panizza 2001). Accordingly, the way that individuals, experience, assess and undergo the electoral process is likely to have an impact on support for democracy (Robbins and Tessler 2012). The literature about the determinants of individual support for democracy in the Arab world can be classified into three groups. The first group of studies refers to modernization theory and to its cultural implications (Inglehart and Norris 2003; Inglehart and Welzel 2005) according to which education, income and egalitarian gender views are significant determinants of attitudes toward democracy (Jamal 2006). The second group of studies refers to social capital theory according to which social trust, by providing a basis for cooperation among the members of a society, is a fundamental ingredient of democracy (Jamal 2007a, 2007b; Almond and Verba 1963; Putnam, Leonardi, and Nanetti 1994). The third group of studies focuses on religiosity and on cultural traits and, as far as the Muslim world is concerned, finds no incompatibility between Islamic values and support for democracy (Ciftci 2012).

In this paper, we argue that there is another determinant of individual support for democracy in the Arab world, namely political particularism. Following Carey and Shugart (1995) and Shugart (1999), political particularism is defined as the ability of policymakers to further their careers by catering to narrow interests rather than to broader national platforms. Political particularism implies the existence of a loyalty between voters and political elites. This loyalty passes through family, clan and friendship obligations (Veenendaal 2014) and, as argued by Weber (1970) and many others, contrasts with modern democratic societies where abstract rules of good conduct apply to several social situations, and not just towards a small circle of personal friends and relatives (Tabellini 2010). [1] The manner in which politicians further their careers and the choices of voters with respect to candidates, are likely to influence how democracy is perceived, supported and manifested as well as the quality of the governments (Hicken and Simmons 2008). As suggested by Seddon et al. (2001), politicians who are supposed to please narrow geographical constituencies, are likely to advocate narrower, more particularistic policies than those who further their career by following party dictates (Milesi-Ferretti, Perotti, and Rostagno 2002). At the same time, voters, who must channel their demands through politics, are likely to prefer candidates who are supposed to accord some benefit to the group they feel to be part of. The way how they perceive the breadth of this group determines their preferences in voting. More universalistic voters would prefer candidates who foster the interests of the entire community whilst more particularistic ones would prefer candidates who foster the interests of a narrower circle of related people (i. e. family, clan, and friends). Traditionally, democracy has been seen as the institution aimed at safeguarding the conflicting interests of the entire community of citizens or, at least, of the majority of them. Thus, particularistic voters are less likely to support democracy and democratic values with respect to more universalistic ones.

Recently in the Arab world there has been an extraordinary outbreak of Islamic movements calling for the construction of an increasingly global, Muslim identity, based on common beliefs, rituals, social practices and for a return to the Shari’a. [2] These movements, apparently universalist, are indeed rooted in the local contexts so that the universalistic Islamic identity often coexists and is pushed by a more particularistic one (Lapidus 2001). As suggested by Ciftci (2012), in the Muslim world Shari’a and democracy are two sides of the same coin and the analysis of individual attitudes toward democracy will be incomplete without considering support for Shari’a. In fact, the historical legacy and the so-called secular-Islamist cleavage have penetrated almost all political issues and actions in the Muslim world (Hunter 1996) by shaping also individual attitudes (Ciftci 2012). This does not mean that in the Arab world Islam is incompatible with democracy. Rather, this means that, as in Tessler (2011), individual opinion in the Arab world is divided about secular and Islamic governing principles and most Arab citizens voice support for both democracy and Shari’a that are, therefore, inextricably linked.

Given the above considerations, our hypotheses are that (1) political particularism negatively affects support for democracy in the Arab World whilst (2) it positively affects support for Shari’a. To empirically test these hypotheses, we fully exploit the richness of the Arab Barometer. Firstly, we show that political particularism, once controlling for modernization theory indicators (education, income, egalitarian gender views) and for indicators of social capital (social and institutional trust), reduces support for democracy. We then show that this result is robust to the use of alternative specifications of the model and of econometric techniques aimed at addressing the potential endogeneity of particularism. Secondly, we investigate the relationship between individual attitudes toward support for democracy and towards support for Shari’a. Overall, our findings indicate that (1) particularism reduces support for democracy. This relationship is, indeed, causal. Moreover, even when allowing for the correlation of the error terms, (2) particularism significantly increases support for Shari’a.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents the data and methods, Section 3 presents the results while Section 4 concludes and suggests avenues for following research.

2 Data and Methods

2.1 Data

Our empirical analysis is based on the second wave of the Arab Barometer, a project developed in consultation with a network composed of regional barometers in Latin America, Sub-Saharan Africa, East and South Asia. [3] Our sample is composed of 10 countries [4] and covers 12,782 individuals for the period 2010–2011. The questionnaire in the Arab Barometer included, among others, questions on citizens’ attitudes about public affairs and governance, religion and religiosity, social capital, family status, employment and satisfaction with the government. One key question on political particularism was also included in the questionnaire: “In general, to what extent is it important to you that the candidate is from your family/tribe in deciding who to vote for in elections?”. For ease of interpretation, we recoded the responses as “not important=1”, “A limited extent=2”, “A medium extent=3” and “A great extent=4”.

Our main variable for support for democracy is measured considering the answers to the questions:

  1. Under a democratic system, the country’s economic performance is weak.

  2. Democratic regimes are indecisive and full of problems.

  3. Democratic systems are not effective at maintaining order and stability.

  4. Democracy negatively affects social and ethical values in your country.

For each item, “strongly agree” was recoded as 1, “agree” was recoded as 2, “disagree” was recoded as 3 and “strongly disagree” was recoded as 4. These four variables were then summed and transformed into an index ranging from 4 to 16 and measuring support for democracy. To assess the robustness of our results a principal component analysis was also conducted and the first factor was extracted. Moreover, a third measure of overall support for democracy was constructed by using the answer to the question: “I will describe different political systems to you, and I want to ask you about your opinion of each one of them with regard to the country’s governance – for each one would you say it is very good, good, bad, or very bad?”. More specifically, respondents were asked to express their opinion regarding “A democratic political system”. For ease of interpretation the answers to this question were recoded with “very bad”=1 and “very good”=4.

Support for Shari’a is measured with an item asking the respondents to evaluate whether a system governed by Islamic law without elections or political parties would be suitable to rule respondents’ countries. The answers are given from a scale from 1 to 4 and were recoded such as “Absolutely inappropriate=1” and “Very appropriate=4”. As such, this variable differentiates weak from ardent supporters of Shari’a (Ciftci 2012).

Among the independent variables, we included gender and age together with a set of indicators of modernization theory. In particular, self-reported measures of education (Level of education), employment status (Employment status) and income (Log income USD dollars) have been used to assess whether increased wealth generate positive attitudes towards democracy. Four measures of trust were used to test the hypotheses related to social capital theory. According to this argument, general trust provides the basis for cooperation among the members of society, it enhances associational activity and reciprocity and, therefore, it is an essential element of regime stability and support of democracy. At the institutional level, institutional trust conveys legitimacy to democratic institutions. Recently Jamal (2007b) has challenged this argument by showing that in authoritarian settings, such as the Middle East, a higher level of social trust is indeed associated with support for the existing regime, and hence negatively related with democracy.

Thus, in our empirical specification we added among the controls a standard dichotomous measure of generalized trust [5] (General trust) together with three measures of institutional trust (Trust Government, Trust Public Security, Trust Army) evaluating confidence in the government, public security and in the army (Jamal 2007a, 2007b). The estimated specifications also include a variable accounting for the time spent in Western countries [6] (Time spent in Western countries), the individual degree of interest in politics (How interested in politics), two measures of institutional satisfaction (Satisfaction with the government[7] and Satisfaction with democracy and human rights[8]) and a measure of Internet use (Internet Use). An item about self-assessed religiosity was also used [9] (Self-assessed religiosity). Summary statistics of all the variables used in our specifications are provided in Table 1.

Table 1:

Summary statistics.

MeanStd.dev.MinMax
Support for democracy11.182.90416
Support for Shari’a1.931.1314
Democratic political system, how good3.410.7214
Support for democracy, pca0.001.62–43
Political Particularism2.271.2214
Gender0.520.5001
Age37.3513.441889
Level of education3.471.3516
Employment status0.490.5001
Log income USD dollars6.181.07–314
General trust0.270.4401
Trust Government2.501.1014
Trust Public Security2.331.0814
Trust Army1.861.0214
How interested in politics2.730.9814
Internet use3.321.1614
Time spent in western countries0.250.8104
Satisfaction with the government3.702.58110
Satisfaction with democracy and human rights in country3.071.1015
Self-assessed religiosity1.720.6113
Instrument
Ethno Linguistic Fractionalization0.420.210.010.67
Observations12,782

The surveyed individuals indicated widespread support for both, democracy and Shari’a in every country in our sample. On average, Egypt shows the highest average score on support for democracy while Jordan the lowest one. As far as support for Shari’a is concerned, Saudi Arabia shows the highest average score while Lebanon shows the lowest one. Accordingly, particularism is at its highest average level in Jordan while it is at its lowest average level in Lebanon. No significant average differences emerge across gender and age. [10]

2.2 Methods

We first estimate a series of OLS regressions including cross-sectional estimation with a progressive larger set of controls and with country fixed effects. As a robustness check, in order to take into account the ordinal nature of the dependent variable, in Table 3 we report ordered logit estimation. Test statistics are based on standard errors robust to heteroskedasticity. We consider also estimates obtained by interacting political particularism with some indicators of modernization theory and institutional satisfaction.

One of the key issues of estimating the relationship between political particularism and support for democracy using survey data is endogeneity of political particularism that prevents the causal interpretation of the results. In fact, our main estimated parameter of interest might be reflecting reverse causation as people who support less democracy are, indeed, more particularists. Moreover, unobserved heterogeneity might result in omitted variable bias since there could be some unobserved factors that determine both political particularism and support for democracy. In order to address these issues, we apply Instrumental Variables (henceforth, IV) techniques. Our identification strategy is based therefore on the estimation of a two equations’ system, the first one describing support for democracy while the second one is the first step in the IV strategy and includes our instrument for political particularism. For an instrument to be reliable it must meet at least two criteria. First, it must be correlated with the endogenous explanatory variable, in our case political particularism, conditional on the other covariates (the so-called relevance condition). Second, it must be uncorrelated with the error term in the explanatory equation, conditional on the other covariates (the so-called orthogonality condition); that is, the instrument cannot suffer from the same problem as the original predicting variable. Since it is not possible to directly test this condition, we should rely on common sense and economic theory to decide which instruments are more suitable for our variable of interest.

In our empirical strategy we use a measure of ethnolinguistic fractionalization at the country level, as the one used in Alesina et al. (2003), as an instrument for individual-level political particularism. Within economics there has been a large and growing literature, beginning with Mauro (1995), using indexes of ethnolinguistic fractionalization either as an instrument or as an explanatory variable for various economic outcomes. A part of this literature has used cross-country data to investigate the effects of ethnolinguistic fractionalization on democracy pointing to inconclusive results.

Empirically, we find that the measure of ethnolinguistic fractionalization is not correlated with individual-level support for democracy. We believe that the level of ethnolinguistic fractionalization cannot per se exert a direct influence on individual-level support for democracy. Rather, it creates the premise for the individual choice. Thus, it is reasonable to assume that the impact of ethnolinguistic fractionalization on support for democracy occurs through the individual-level political particularism. To put it otherwise, following Jensen and Skaaning (2012), we claim that ethnolinguistic fractionalization is a conditional factor only indirectly explaining support for democracy by moderating the effect of modernization and by increasing particularistic attitudes.

After assessing the causal effect of political particularism on support for democracy, we investigate the relationship between individual attitudes toward democracy and individual attitudes towards Shari’a. Empirically, we control for the dependency between the individual-level determinants of both, support for Shari’a and support for democracy. Since we assume the error terms of both equations to be correlated, we run both equations simultaneously by means of a seemingly unrelated model (henceforth, SUR) and we estimate the full variance–covariance matrix of the coefficients.

3 Results

Table 2 presents the results of the OLS estimations. Political particularism has a negative and significant effect on support for democracy. [11] This result stays virtually unchanged across all specifications of the model and is robust to the use of alternative definitions as described in Section 2 and reported in Table 4 and to the estimation by Ordered Logit as reported in Table 3. [12]

Table 2:

Support for democracy, OLS estimation.

(1)(2)(3)
Political Particularism–0.30***–0.31***–0.33***
(0.02)(0.03)(0.03)
Gender0.060.070.08
(0.06)(0.06)(0.08)
Age0.00**0.01**0.00
(0.00)(0.00)(0.00)
Level of education0.11***0.11***0.10***
(0.02)(0.03)(0.03)
Employed0.100.070.11
(0.06)(0.07)(0.08)
Log income USD dollars0.14***0.15***0.13***
(0.04)(0.04)(0.05)
General trust–0.07–0.21**
(0.07)(0.08)
Trust Government–0.040.02
(0.04)(0.05)
Trust Public Security0.01–0.01
(0.04)(0.05)
Trust Army0.16***0.17***
(0.04)(0.05)
How interested in politics–0.08*
(0.04)
Internet use0.06*
(0.03)
Time spent in western countries0.03
(0.05)
Satisfaction with the government–0.01
(0.02)
Satisfaction with democracy and human rights in country0.05
(0.04)
Self-assessed religiosity–0.05
(0.06)
Constant10.57***10.21***10.71***
(0.29)(0.31)(0.51)
Observations9,9749,2956,114
Country dummiesYesYesYes
Table 3:

Robustness check, Ordered Logit Estimation.

Support for democracy
Political Particularism–0.22***
(0.02)
Gender0.05
(0.05)
Age0.00
(0.00)
Level of education0.05**
(0.02)
Employed0.07
(0.05)
Log income USD dollars0.09***
(0.03)
General trust–0.13**
(0.05)
Trust Government0.02
(0.03)
Trust Public Security–0.01
(0.03)
Trust Army0.11***
(0.03)
How interested in politics–0.05**
(0.03)
Internet Use0.04*
(0.02)
Time spent in western countries0.00
(0.03)
Satisfaction with the government–0.01
(0.01)
Satisfaction with democracy and human rights in country0.01
(0.03)
Self-assessed religiosity–0.02
(0.04)
cut1
Constant–3.89***
(0.33)
cut2
Constant–3.32***
(0.33)
cut3
Constant–2.69***
(0.32)
cut4
Constant–2.06***
(0.32)
cut5
Constant–1.40***
(0.32)
cut6
Constant–0.90***
(0.32)
cut7
Constant–0.45
(0.32)
cut8
Constant0.04
(0.32)
cut9
Constant1.05***
(0.32)
cut10
Constant1.66***
(0.32)
cut11
Constant2.09***
(0.32)
cut12
Constant2.56***
(0.32)
Observations6,114
Country dummiesYes

The size of the effect is small in absolute terms, ranging between 0.30 and 0.33 points, similarly to related studies based on micro data (e. g., Rotondi and Stanca 2015). Indeed, in relative terms the size of the effect of particularism is sizeable, being larger than that of education, employment status, income and all other individual-level characteristics. Particularism is therefore by far the strongest factor explaining individual-level support for democracy. The inclusion of measures of interest in politics provides a test of the role of political attention in mediating particularism’s impact on democratic attitudes (Evans and Rose 2012). Column 3 of Table 2 shows that the introduction of this variable (which is negative and significantly related with support for democracy), does not attenuate the size of the coefficient for particularism which is, indeed, increased.

Among the indicators of modernization theory, education and income have positive and significant effects on support for democracy with the latter effect being greater than the former, confirming some previous findings (Lipset 1959; Evans and Rose 2012). Among the indicators of social capital theory, general trust is statistically significant with a negative coefficient, a result that corroborates the findings in Jamal (2007b). Trust in army and Internet use turn out to be positively and significantly related to support for democracy. Religiosity does not exhibit statistical significance in either model, which is congruent with the findings of previous studies (Tessler 2002a and 2002b).

The second and third lines of Table 5 report the results of estimating the same equation as in column 3 of Table 2 while adding interaction terms between political particularism and two indicators of modernization theory, namely education and income. While the first interaction term does not reach statistical significance, the interaction term between political particularism and income suggests that the negative effect of political particularism on individual-level support for democracy is greater as income increases. The fourth and fifth lines of Table 5 report the results of estimating the same equation as in column 3 of Table 2 while adding interaction terms between political particularism and two indicators of institutional satisfaction, namely satisfaction with the actual government ruling the country (fourth line) and with the state of democracy and human rights in the country (fifth line). It turns out that the effect of political particularism on support for democracy is greater when support for actual government increases and is smaller as satisfaction with the state of democracy increases.

The main message of the regressions in Tables 26 is that there seems to be a strong correlation between political particularism and individual-level support for democracy and that this relationship is moderated by individual-level income and satisfaction with the government and with the state of democracy in the country of origin.

Table 4:

Robustness check, alternative indicators.

(1)(2)
Democratic political system, how goodSupport for democracy, pca
Political Particularism–0.16***–0.19***
(0.02)(0.02)
Gender0.030.05
(0.06)(0.05)
Age0.01***0.00
(0.00)(0.00)
Level of education0.07***0.06***
(0.02)(0.02)
Employed0.030.06
(0.06)(0.05)
Log income USD dollars0.06*0.07***
(0.03)(0.03)
General trust0.01–0.12**
(0.06)(0.05)
Trust Government0.040.01
(0.03)(0.03)
Trust Public Security0.02–0.00
(0.03)(0.03)
Trust Army–0.06*0.09***
(0.03)(0.03)
How interested in politics–0.17***–0.05*
(0.03)(0.02)
Internet Use–0.010.03*
(0.02)(0.02)
Time spent in western countries–0.050.02
(0.04)(0.03)
Satisfaction with the government–0.01–0.01
(0.01)(0.01)
Satisfaction with democracy and human rights in country–0.010.03
(0.03)(0.02)
Self-assessed religiosity0.15***–0.03
(0.04)(0.04)
–0.16***–0.19***
Constant–0.28
(0.29)
cut1
Constant–3.69***
(0.34)
cut2
Constant–2.19***
(0.34)
cut3
Constant0.32
(0.34)
Observations6,7406,114
Country dummiesYesYes
Table 5:

Support for democracy, interactions with particularism.

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Political Particularism–0.42***–1.08***–0.47***–0.59***
(0.09)(0.20)(0.06)(0.10)
Particularism*Education0.03
(0.02)
Particularism*Income0.12***
(0.03)
Particularism*Government Satisfaction0.04***
(0.01)
Particularism*Satisfaction with democracy–0.08***
(0.03)
Observations6,1146,1146,1146,114
Standard ControlsYesYesYesYes
Country dummiesYesYesYesYes
Table 6:

Support for democracy, OLS estimation by country.

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
AlgeriaEgyptIraqJordanLebanonPalestineSaudi ArabiaSudanTunisiaYemen
Political Particularism0.14–0.64***–0.75***–0.22**–0.23**–0.14*0.22–0.33***–0.41***–0.02
(0.10)(0.08)(0.08)(0.09)(0.10)(0.08)(0.19)(0.10)(0.10)(0.10)
Gender0.020.61***0.000.04–0.02–0.23–0.38–0.10–0.09–0.30
(0.25)(0.23)(0.20)(0.28)(0.24)(0.27)(0.45)(0.24)(0.24)(0.24)
Age–0.000.00–0.010.000.000.00–0.000.020.02*–0.00
(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.02)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)
Education–0.22*–0.01–0.110.170.36***0.34***0.080.090.140.19*
(0.11)(0.07)(0.09)(0.12)(0.11)(0.12)(0.22)(0.09)(0.10)(0.10)
Employed0.310.28–0.110.14–0.140.010.26–0.070.20–0.03
(0.25)(0.22)(0.21)(0.28)(0.25)(0.27)(0.43)(0.25)(0.23)(0.26)
Income–0.370.100.050.070.73***0.210.11–0.12–0.02–0.03
(0.26)(0.13)(0.06)(0.19)(0.23)(0.15)(0.34)(0.23)(0.19)(0.19)
General trust–0.89*–0.15–0.53**–0.240.19–0.00–1.41**–0.39–0.200.00
(0.48)(0.21)(0.24)(0.25)(0.26)(0.23)(0.58)(0.29)(0.23)(0.25)
Trust Government–0.210.22*–0.03–0.070.10–0.05–0.220.30*–0.200.16
(0.20)(0.12)(0.14)(0.14)(0.17)(0.14)(0.40)(0.17)(0.13)(0.16)
Trust Public Security–0.38–0.36***0.02–0.14–0.05–0.060.140.080.34***–0.20
(0.26)(0.10)(0.16)(0.15)(0.14)(0.15)(0.38)(0.15)(0.12)(0.16)
Trust Army0.66***–0.42**0.68***0.280.150.150.72**–0.10–0.28*0.30**
(0.24)(0.21)(0.14)(0.18)(0.12)(0.14)(0.29)(0.15)(0.15)(0.15)
How interested in politics0.110.02–0.16–0.13–0.100.010.57**–0.26**0.23*–0.33**
(0.19)(0.11)(0.12)(0.12)(0.11)(0.11)(0.24)(0.13)(0.13)(0.13)
Internet Use0.130.03–0.100.020.32***0.070.26–0.03–0.20*0.04
(0.13)(0.13)(0.10)(0.09)(0.12)(0.08)(0.22)(0.09)(0.11)(0.11)
Time spent in western countries0.34***–0.89***0.340.28**0.20*0.37**0.35*–0.27*0.09–0.20
(0.10)(0.17)(0.23)(0.12)(0.10)(0.17)(0.20)(0.15)(0.11)(0.45)
Satisfaction with the government0.13–0.16***0.32***–0.00–0.070.02–0.51***0.02–0.19***0.07
(0.09)(0.05)(0.05)(0.06)(0.07)(0.05)(0.14)(0.05)(0.06)(0.06)
Satisfaction with democracy and human rights in country0.190.20*0.53***–0.14–0.150.190.11–0.090.04–0.26**
(0.23)(0.11)(0.11)(0.14)(0.12)(0.12)(0.21)(0.13)(0.14)(0.12)
Self-assessed religiosity–0.65***0.70***–0.77***0.08–0.05–0.47***0.33–0.220.38**–0.39**
(0.19)(0.19)(0.17)(0.19)(0.18)(0.18)(0.35)(0.19)(0.18)(0.18)
Constant10.75***14.20***9.27***10.63***5.21***6.47***10.13***10.97***12.63***10.38***
(2.22)(1.20)(1.09)(1.68)(1.94)(1.28)(3.51)(1.69)(1.45)(1.51)
Observations422861810595912551188723528524

3.1 Addressing Causality

Table 7 reports IV estimation results. The first column reports the estimation of the first stage equation. The power of the instrument exceeds the conventional minimum standard of power of F = 10 (Stock, Wright, and Yogo 2002). [13] The results of the IV estimation are statistically significant and in line with our theoretical prediction: political particularism decreases support for democracy. Indeed, the size of the estimated effect is even larger when using IV, suggesting that failing to account for the endogeneity of particularism may lead to underestimating its effect on support for democracy.

Table 7:

Instrumental variables regression.

(1)(2)
First Stage Political ParticularismIV Support for democracy
Ethno Linguistic Fractionalization0.25***
(0.07)
Political Particularism–1.48**
(0.75)
Gender0.030.08
(0.03)(0.09)
Age–0.00**–0.00
(0.00)(0.00)
Level of education–0.020.00
(0.01)(0.04)
Employed–0.06*0.03
(0.03)(0.10)
Log income USD dollars0.10***0.28***
(0.02)(0.08)
General trust0.02–0.10
(0.03)(0.09)
Trust Government–0.04**–0.08
(0.02)(0.05)
Trust Public Security–0.020.09
(0.02)(0.06)
Trust Army0.05***0.02
(0.02)(0.06)
How interested in politics0.07***–0.04
(0.02)(0.07)
Internet Use–0.020.10***
(0.01)(0.04)
Time spent in western countries0.03*0.09
(0.02)(0.06)
Satisfaction with the government0.05***–0.05
(0.01)(0.05)
Satisfaction with democracy and human rights in country0.06***0.13**
(0.02)(0.06)
Self-assessed religiosity–0.01–0.14**
(0.02)(0.07)
Constant1.31***12.26***
(0.16)(1.24)
Observations6,0976,114
Country dummiesYes

3.2 Support for Democracy and Support for Shari’a

Table 8 reports the results of the SUR model. The findings indicate that, for the individual, the correlation of the residuals in the two equations is –0.1828 and that the hypothesis that this correlation is zero is rejected. [14] Therefore, given the peculiar structure of the Muslim world, it is not advisable to study support for democracy without considering support for Shari’a (Ciftci 2012).

Table 8:

SUR model.

(1)(1)
Support for Shari’aSupport for democracy
Political Particularism0.04***–0.34***
(0.01)(0.03)
Gender–0.030.08
(0.03)(0.08)
Age–0.00***0.00
(0.00)(0.00)
Level of education–0.03***0.13***
(0.01)(0.03)
Employed–0.040.12
(0.03)(0.09)
Log income USD dollars–0.010.12**
(0.02)(0.05)
General trust–0.01–0.19**
(0.03)(0.09)
Trust Government–0.03*0.02
(0.02)(0.05)
Trust Public Security0.05***0.01
(0.02)(0.05)
Trust Army–0.020.17***
(0.02)(0.05)
How interested in politics0.07***–0.07*
(0.01)(0.04)
Internet Use–0.02*0.07*
(0.01)(0.04)
Time spent in western countries0.04**0.02
(0.02)(0.05)
Satisfaction with the government0.01–0.01
(0.01)(0.02)
Satisfaction with democracy and human rights in country0.09***0.05
(0.01)(0.04)
Self-assessed religiosity0.10***–0.04
(0.02)(0.20)
Constant1.29***10.54***
(0.18)(0.51)
Observations5,8355,835
Country dummiesYesYes

Political particularism significantly reduces support for democracy whilst it increases support for Shari’a. This opposite effect (in the same direction) is found for education. The higher the level of education, the lower is the support of Shari’a and the higher is the support for democracy. Other covariates indicate that trust in government is negatively correlated with both support for Shari’a and support for democracy although in the latter case it is not significant. Surprisingly, the time spent in western countries is positively and significantly correlated with support for Shari’a while it turns out to be negatively although not significantly related to support for democracy. The same pattern is found for interest in politics. On the opposite, while religiosity does not reach statistical significance for support for democracy, it is positively related to support for Shari’a.

4 Conclusion

In this article we have further explored the underlying dynamics of individual-level support for democracy and support for Shari’a in the Arab world. In particular, we have investigated how political particularism affects these attitudes at the individual level. Our results show that particularism decreases support for democracy. Indeed, in relative terms, the size of the effect of particularism is substantial, being larger than that of education, employment status, income (as posited by modernization theory) and social trust (as posited by social capital theory), hence all other individual-level characteristics. Particularism is therefore by far the strongest factor explaining individual-level support for democracy in the Arab world and its effect on support for democracy is, indeed, causal. Thus, reducing political particularism can be identified as an effective way to increase support for democracy.

Our underlying claim is that voters with a more universalistic stance would prefer candidates who foster the interests of the entire community whilst more particularistic inclined ones would prefer candidates who foster the interests of a narrower circle of related people (i. e. family, clan, and friends). This relates to the distinction between “generalized” versus “limited” morality introduced by Platteau (2000) and stressed by Tabellini (2010) and with the extensive literature showing that particularism is often associated with more widespread informal institutions (Mungiu-Pippidi 2005), lower civic mindedness and higher corruption (Uslaner 2002).

In this perspective, social relations in particularistic societies rely on strong ties informed by principles of tradition, conformity and benevolence inside small circles of related people (i. e., members of the family, friends, and members of the clan) while outside this small network, selfish behavior is considered morally acceptable (Tabellini 2010). Particularism, therefore, can be conducive to several antisocial behaviors and, potentially, can undermine the cohesion of the social fabric. Thus, studying the effects of particularism is relevant to inform development practitioners and policy makers. To date, the determinants of particularism at the individual-level are still unclear and it is not easy to formulate some clear policy interventions to reduce particularism and favor universalism (Rotondi and Stanca 2015). Some scholars have indicated education as the most promising area of intervention. In fact, as argued by Glaeser, Ponzetto, and Shleifer (2007), education enhances social trust thus contributing to overcoming problems of collective action. The relationship between education and particularism, however, is not completely clear and further researches in this direction are needed.

Following Ciftci (2012), in this paper we have also studied how particularism affects support for Shari’a, another side of support for democracy in the Arab world. Our summary statistics show that several supporters of democracy also favor Shari’a in the Arab world. At the same time, the results of the estimation of a simultaneous equation model show that when allowing for the correlation of the error terms, particularism increases support for Shari’a while it decreases support for democracy.

These findings offer new insights into challenges of building widespread support for democracy in the Arab world, particularly after the Arab spring. Our conclusions, however, should be weighedagainst some weaknesses of public opinion data. Greater caution is needed about the available measures of support for democracy. In fact, the existing data do not tell us anything about what respondents really mean by democracy, or, ultimately, how they perceive it. To date, data on support for democracy are diffused and several major empirical research programs are monitoring public support for democratic institutions, including, among others, the LatinoBarometer, the AfroBarometer, the European Values Survey, and the World Values Survey. The questions contained in these datasets are regularly used by scholars in different fields and demonstrate internal consistency. However, as Inglehart (2003), suggests while from a theoretical point of view the relationship between support for democracy and democratic institutions seems to be clear, there is still some doubts regarding whether, at the empirical level,high level of mass support for these issues is actually conducive to democratic institutions. These and other issues should be further investigatedin future research work in the Arab world.

Funding statement: National Research University Higher School of Economics. The article was prepared within the framework of a subsidy granted to the HSE by the Government of the Russian Federation for the implementation of the Global Competitiveness Program.

References

Alesina, A., et al. 2003. “Fractionalization.” Journal of Economic Growth 8 (2):155–94.10.3386/w9411Search in Google Scholar

Almond, G., and S. Verba. 1963. The Civic Culture: Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations. Center for International Studies, Princeton University: Little, Brown.10.1515/9781400874569Search in Google Scholar

Carey, J., and M. Shugart. 1995. “Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas.” Electoral Studies 14 (4):417–39.10.1016/0261-3794(94)00035-2Search in Google Scholar

Ciftci, S. 2012. “Secular-Islamist Cleavage, Values, and Support for Democracy and Shari’a in the Arab World.” Political Research Quarterly 66 (4):781–93.10.1177/1065912912470759Search in Google Scholar

de Miguel, C., A. A. Jamal, and M. Tessler. 2015. “Elections in the Arab World: Why Do Citizens Turn Out?” Comparative Political Studies. April 21, 2015 0010414015574877. Published online before print April 21, 2015, doi: 10.1177/0010414015574877.Search in Google Scholar

Diamond, L. 1999. Developing Democracy: Toward Consolidation. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.10.56021/9780801860140Search in Google Scholar

Evans, G., and P. Rose. 2012. “Understanding Education’s Influence on Support for Democracy in Sub-Saharan Africa.” The Journal of Development Studies 48 (4):498–515.10.1080/00220388.2011.598508Search in Google Scholar

Glaeser, E., G. Ponzetto, and A. Shleifer. 2007. “Why Does Democracy Need Education?” Journal of Economic Growth 12 (2):77–99.10.3386/w12128Search in Google Scholar

Hicken, A., and J. W. Simmons. 2008. “The Personal Vote and the Efficacy of Education Spending.” American Journal of Political Science 52 (1):109–24.10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00302.xSearch in Google Scholar

Hunter, S. 1996. “The Rise of Islamist Movements and the Western Response: Clash of Civilizations or Clash of Interests?” In The Islamist Dilemma: The Political Role of Islamist Movements in the Contemporary Arab World, International Politics of the Middle East Series, 3:317–50, Ithaca.Search in Google Scholar

Inglehart, R. 2003. “How Solid Is Mass Support for Democracy—and How Can We Measure It?” Political Science and Politics, 1:51–7.10.1017/S1049096503001689Search in Google Scholar

Inglehart, R., and P. Norris. 2003. “The True Clash of Civilizations.” Foreign Policy, No. 135. (March–April, 2003), 62–70.10.2307/3183594Search in Google Scholar

Inglehart, R., and C. Welzel. 2005. Modernization, Cultural Change, and Democracy: The Human Development Sequence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Jamal, A. 2006. “Reassessing Support for Islam and Democracy in the Arab World? Evidence from Egypt and Jordan.” World Affairs 169.2 (2006):51–63.10.3200/WAFS.169.2.51-63Search in Google Scholar

Jamal, A. 2007a. Barriers to Democracy: The Other Side of Social Capital in Palestine and the Arab World. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400830503Search in Google Scholar

Jamal, A. 2007b. “When Is Social Trust a Desirable Outcome?” Comparative Political Studies 40:1328–49.10.1177/0010414006291833Search in Google Scholar

Jensen, C., and S. Skaaning. 2012. “Modernization, Ethnic Fractionalization, and Democracy.” Democratization 19 (6):1117–37.10.1080/13510347.2011.619777Search in Google Scholar

Lapidus, I. M. 2001. “Between Universalism and Particularism: The Historical Bases of Muslim Communal, National, and Global Identities.” Global Networks 1.1 (2001):37–55.10.1111/1471-0374.00004Search in Google Scholar

Lipset, S. 1959. “Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy.” American Political Science Review 53 (1):69–105.10.2307/1951731Search in Google Scholar

Lipset, S. M. 1960. Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Mauro, P. 1995. “Corruption and Growth.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (3):681–712.10.2307/2946696Search in Google Scholar

Milesi-Ferretti, G., R. Perotti, and M. Rostagno. 2002. “Electoral Systems and Public Spending.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (2):609–57.10.1162/003355302753650346Search in Google Scholar

Mungiu‐Pippidi, A. 2005. “Deconstructing Balkan Particularism: The Ambiguous Social Capital of Southeastern Europe.” Southeast European and Black Sea Studies 5 (1):49–68.10.1080/1468385042000328367Search in Google Scholar

Panizza, U. 2001. “Electoral Rules, Political Systems, and Institutional Quality.” Economics & Politics 13 (3):311–42.10.2139/ssrn.192113Search in Google Scholar

Platteau, J.-P. 2000. Institutions, Social Norms, and Economic Development 1. Psychology Press: Academic Publishers & Routledge.Search in Google Scholar

Putnam, R. D., R. Leonardi, and R. Y. Nanetti. 1994. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. s.l.: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400820740Search in Google Scholar

Robbins, M., and M. Tessler. 2012. “The Effect of Elections on Public Opinion Toward Democracy Evidence From Longitudinal Survey Research in Algeria.” Comparative Political Studies 45 (10):1255–76.10.1177/0010414011434296Search in Google Scholar

Rotondi, V., and L. Stanca. 2015. “The Effect of Particularism on Corruption: Theory and Empirical Evidence.” Journal of Economic Psychology, December 51:219–35.10.1016/j.joep.2015.09.008Search in Google Scholar

Seddon, J., A. Gaviria, U. Panizza, and E. Stein. 2001. “Political Particularism around the World.” Available at SSRN 286281.10.2139/ssrn.286281Search in Google Scholar

Shugart, M. 1999. Efficiency and Reform: A New Index of Government Responsiveness and the Conjunction of Electoral and Economic Reform. San Diego: Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, Universidad de California.Search in Google Scholar

Stock, J., J. Wright, and M. Yogo. 2002. “A Survey of Weak Instruments and Weak Identification in Generalized Method of Moments.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20 (4):518–29.10.1198/073500102288618658Search in Google Scholar

Svolik, M. W. 2013. “Learning to Love Democracy: Electoral Accountability and the Success of Democracy.” American Journal of Political Science 57 (3):685–702.10.1111/ajps.12005Search in Google Scholar

Tabellini, G. 2010. “Culture and Institutions: Economic Development in the Regions of Europe.” Journal of the European Economic Association 8 (4):677–716.10.1111/j.1542-4774.2010.tb00537.xSearch in Google Scholar

Tessler, M. 2002a. “Do Islamic Orientations Influence Attitudes Toward Democracy in the Arab World? Evidence From Egypt, Jordan, Morocco, and Algeria.” International Journal of Comparative Sociology 43 (3–5):229–49.10.1177/002071520204300302Search in Google Scholar

Tessler, M. 2002b. “Islam and Democracy in the Middle East: The Impact of Religious Orientations on Attitudes Toward Democracy in Four Arab Countries.” Comparative Politics, April 34 (3):337–54.10.2307/4146957Search in Google Scholar

Tessler, M. 2011. “Popular Views About Islam and Politics in the Arab World.” International Institute Journal 1 (1):1–3.Search in Google Scholar

Uslaner, E. M. 2002. The Moral Foundations of Trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.2139/ssrn.824504Search in Google Scholar

Veenendaal, W. 2014. Politics and Democracy in Microstates 29. London: Routledge.10.4324/9781315761909Search in Google Scholar

Weber, M. 1970. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Australia: George Allen and Unwin.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2016-8-12
Published in Print: 2016-8-1

©2016 by De Gruyter

Downloaded on 21.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rmeef-2016-0004/html
Scroll to top button