Home Lawyers and Investment
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Lawyers and Investment

  • Baptiste Massenot EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: January 14, 2014
Become an author with De Gruyter Brill

Abstract

This paper presents a model of lawyers and investment. Investors use litigation to enforce their financial contracts with entrepreneurs. Litigation is modeled as a contest in which both agents hire lawyers to increase their probability of winning the trial. The issue and the cost of the contest determine how much investors are willing to lend. The model predicts that (i) more lawyers are hired if judicial efficiency is lower or damages are higher; (ii) higher judicial efficiency, higher damages, and tighter restrictions on the supply of lawyers benefit investment. Thus, the number of lawyers can be negatively correlated with economic activity even though lawyers are assumed to be productive.

Appendix

Proof of Result 3

Differentiating eqs [5] and [23] with respect to j gives:

Assume , then we have:

We know that the first term is positive, the second is negative, and the third is positive. A sufficient condition for this inequality to be true is that the sum of the second and third terms is positive. Then, focusing on these two terms:

Replacing , gives:

Using eq. [23] to replace w gives:

The last inequality is true. Thus, this proves .

Differentiating eqs [5] and [23] with respect to d gives:

Assume , then we have:

The last inequality is true. Thus, this proves .

and

I now prove that Result 3 is strengthened if , in particular, if . Because only enters the demand for engineers , it only affects through . From eq. [4], This implies that the effect of j on is decreasing in . Because negatively affects , this implies that Result 3 strengthens when increases. A similar reasoning applies to d.

References

Carbonara, E., and F.Parisi. 2012. “Rent-Seeking and Litigation: The Hidden Virtues of the Loser-Pays Rule,” Minnesota Legal Studies Research Paper1239.10.2139/ssrn.2144800Search in Google Scholar

Carmignani, A., and S.Giacomelli. 2010. “Too Many Lawyers? Litigation in Italian Civil Courts,” Working paper.10.2139/ssrn.1669988Search in Google Scholar

Dixit, A. 1987. “Strategic Behavior in Contests,” The American Economic Review891898.Search in Google Scholar

Galanter, M. 1993. “Predators and Parasites: Lawyer-Bashing and Civil Justice,” 28Georgia Law Review633.Search in Google Scholar

Gale, D., and M.Hellwig. 1985. “Incentive-Compatible Debt Contracts: The One-Period Problem,” The Review of Economic Studies647663.10.2307/2297737Search in Google Scholar

Gennaioli, N. 2013. “Optimal Contracts with Enforcement Risk,” 11Journal of the European Economic Association.10.1111/j.1542-4774.2012.01107.xSearch in Google Scholar

Gennaioli, N., and E.Perotti. 2012. “Standardized Enforcement: Access to Justice vs Contractual Innovation,” Working paper.Search in Google Scholar

Hadfield, G. K. 2000. “The Price of Law: How the Market for Lawyers Distorts the Justice System,” 98(4) Michigan Law Review9531006.10.2307/1290336Search in Google Scholar

Katz, A. 1988. “Judicial Decision making and Litigation Expenditure,” 8(2) International Review of Law and Economics127143.Search in Google Scholar

Magee, S. P., W. A.Brock, and L.Young. 1989. Black Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory: Political Economy in General Equilibrium. Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Massenot, B. 2011. “Financial Development in Adversarial and Inquisitorial Legal Systems,” 39Journal of Comparative Economics602608.10.1016/j.jce.2011.07.003Search in Google Scholar

Massenot, B.2012. “Why Do Some Countries Have So Many More Lawyers Than Others?” Working paper.Search in Google Scholar

Murphy, K. M., A.Shleifer, and R. W.Vishny. 1991. “The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth,” 106(2) The Quarterly Journal of Economics503530.10.2307/2937945Search in Google Scholar

Rosen, S. 1992. “The Market for Lawyers,” 35Journal of Law & Economics215.10.1086/467252Search in Google Scholar

Spier, K. E. 2007. “Litigation,” 1Handbook of Law and Economics259342.10.1016/S1574-0730(07)01004-3Search in Google Scholar

  1. 1

    Damages are assumed to be exogenous to keep parsimony. Damages can be computed differently in different countries, especially in complex cases, and judges may be more or less severe. Keeping damages exogenous thus makes the framework more widely applicable.

  2. 2

    An alternative way of modeling the asymmetry that arises between the two litigants would be to assume that the dishonest party is less productive at producing arguments.

  3. 3

    See Carbonara and Parisi (2012) for further details on how the loser-pays rule would modify the analysis.

  4. 4

    Unlike lawyers, judges are not drawn from the population of workers. This is an arbitrary choice that is motivated by several considerations. First, if the number of judges was drawn from the population and was exogenous, this would not influence any of the results since this would amount to a situation where the overall supply of labor is lower but still exogenous. A perhaps more interesting case would be if the number of judges was endogenously determined. However, this would require to add a whole new mechanism of how this process works, which would be out of the current focus of the paper.

Published Online: 2014-01-14

©2014 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin / Boston

Downloaded on 9.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rle-2012-0022/html
Scroll to top button