Home The Yemeni Conflicts: A Mismatch Theory Interpretation
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

The Yemeni Conflicts: A Mismatch Theory Interpretation

  • Rebecca Cambrini ORCID logo and Luca Zanotti ORCID logo EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: December 18, 2020

Abstract

This article examines the causes of the current centrist and secessionist civil conflicts in Yemen. We argue that it is possible to explain the outbreak of the struggle of the Houthis against the central government as well as the acceleration of southern secessionist demands in light of the mismatch theory developed by Herrera, Morelli, and Nunnari (2019). In line with this model, we show that the two conflicts erupted once the relatively low political-economic power of the Houthis and of the southern secessionists was no longer matched by a parallel imbalance in their relative military strength vis-à-vis the central government. To examine the implications of the theory in Yemen, we use qualitative evidence on the two ongoing conflicts. The Yemeni case suggests that conflicts exhibiting a non-parallel asymmetry in relative military strength and political-economic power between the warring actors can be interpreted in light of the mismatch theory, regardless of their direction or the objectives their players pursue.


Corresponding author: Luca Zanotti, Università Bocconi, Milan, Italy, E-mail:

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Professor Massimo Morelli, who has guided us throughout our work with practical comments and whose insights on the mismatch theory allowed us to have a sound theoretical basis on which to start our research. For helpful comments and criticisms, we also thank two anonymous reviewers. Finally, we acknowledge the support of Eleonora Ardemagni, who has been so kind to share with us her knowledge on the Yemeni context through useful observations and material.

Appendix

Focusing on separatists, we can apply a formal model drawn from Morelli and Rohner (2015) to outline how the location of resources and the concentration of the group involved predicts the secessionist direction of the fight that broke out between the STC and the Hadi government.

Southern separatists, who are geographically concentrated by definition, are on the sidelines of Yemeni politics and have complained heavily about being plundered of their natural resources. Although some oil reserves also exist in the north (for example in the Ma’rib region), 80% of Yemeni oil is located in the southern governorates of Hadhramaut and Shabwah. Moreover, the only gas terminal in the country is in the southern city of Balhaf. In the Yemeni case, before the intervention of the UAE made secessionists at least as strong as the government, their relative military strength did not mirror the fact that they were richly endowed in natural resources. In other words, the elite in power, rather than southerners, controlled southern natural resources by deciding how to allocate their revenues, as the government was stronger militarily. Hence, by seceding, southern Yemen would have had the opportunity to autonomously enjoy the revenues that its natural resources generate, as it would have had complete control over them.

We now introduce the model. Assume the Yemeni state comprises only two regions, north (1) and south (2), inhabited respectively by two major groups, a pro-government one (A) and a separatist one (B), with population sizes NA1, NB1, NA2 and NB2 (N indicates total population). Assume that A is in power and that each group is particularly concentrated in one of the two regions. In particular, as we already know, the pro-government group is concentrated in the north or region 1, while secessionists are southerners and can thus be found mainly in region 2. R1 and R2 are the values of the extractable resources in region 1 and 2.

Group A controls the ensuing revenues and decides which fraction β of the total surplus R = R1 + R2 can be distributed to the group of separatists B. In turn, group B can choose between accepting that arrangement peacefully (action p), start a centrist war (action c), or request a secession (action s), implying a separation between the two regions. In the latter case, group B would attempt to make South Yemen or region 2 an independent state governed by southern secessionists themselves.

Group A can also trigger a centrist war (in other words, a preventive repression of the minority group), or wait for B’s choice and react to it. Assuming that a faction’s military power is roughly proportional to its population size, in case of a centrist conflict, separatists win with probability Pc=NBNA+NB+γ, where γ is the advantage accumulated by the group in power A and that may also include relative wealth. If B asks for a secession, group A can accept it or fight against it. In the latter case, B wins with probability Ps=NB2NA2+NB2+γ, where γ is A’s accumulated advantage only in region 2.

The separatist group has a higher probability of winning a secessionist conflict than a centrist conflict if NB2N2>NBN, meaning that it is particularly concentrated in region 2 as by construction the case of southern secessionists is, and/or if γ>γ. In the Yemeni case, one possible mechanism that decreased the advantage accumulated by the state in the south was the fact that secessionists were allied with the UAE.

We now turn to the computation of expected utilities to understand when the incentive for southern separatists to trigger a secessionist conflict materializes. The peaceful status quo gives them a payoff β (R1 + R2). Secessionists’ expected utility from a centrist conflict is NBN+γR1+R2dcB, where dcB is the destruction cost of a centrist war for group B. Instead, secessionists’ expected utility from a secession is NB2N2+γR2dsB with dsB < dcB (dsB is the destruction cost of a secession for group B).

Assume that dsA<NA2+γγN2+γR2, meaning that the government never accepts a secession peacefully. This assumption is credible in the Yemeni scenario: the south is vital for the survival of the state given its strategic position for oil shipments and the fact that a significant part of its revenues come from natural resources, which in turn are mainly concentrated in Hadhramaut and Shabwah, as already stressed. Hence, it seems likely that the government in Sana’a would fight back any secession attempt by southern governorates. One concrete example that can be mentioned with respect to the fights that took place between supporters of Hadi and secessionists is the Aden battle of January 2018.

Both the government and the secessionists have a threshold for β beyond which peace is less convenient than fighting: there is a minimum share of resources βs southerners require from the government not to start attempting a secession, but simultaneously there is a maximum β beyond which the government will prefer to fight rather than extending the share of resources it gives to group B. βs can be found by equating the payoff for group B from peace with its expected utility from a secession:

βR1+R2=NB2N2+γR2dsB

which can be rewritten as

βs=NB2N2+γR2RdsBR

Group B prefers peace over secession when ββs, that is when the share of resources the government concedes is higher than the minimum percentage separatists request. β can be found by equating the payoff for A from peace with its expected utility from a centrist war:

1βR=1NBN+γRdcA

which can be rewritten as

β=NBN+γ+dcAR

The government prefers the status quo as long as ββ. Hence, the condition for peace is βsβ. When NB2N2+γR2NBN+γR>dcA+dsB, there is no value of β that leads both groups to choose peace. In other words, there is no bargaining space for secessionists and the government to find a compromise since βs>β. This was the deadlock the STC and the Yemeni government found themselves in.

The model just outlined is such that war becomes almost unavoidable when natural resources are mostly present in the region where the out-of-government group, or southern secessionists in our case, is more concentrated and/or when conflict is not too costly. In this respect, although we recognize that costs may be high in terms of destruction of natural resources and related infrastructures (even though they may be not in terms of opportunity costs since the country is very poor), we still believe that the concentration of resources and the history of marginalization made the incentive to secede outcompete these costs. With respect to resources, given that 80% of them are in South Yemen we can argue that they are present almost exclusively in region 2, hence RR2. In this scenario, even if we had assumed that γγ, meaning that the central government has no particular difficulties in fighting in the territory of secessionists, we would have had that the condition for war dcA+dsBR2<NB2N2+γNBN+γ would have been satisfied because R2 is really high and the out-of-government secessionist group is concentrated in region 2; all of this outweighs the fact that the cost of destroying natural resources may be high.

References

ACLED. 2019. Over 100,000 Reported Killed in Yemen War. https://acleddata.com/2019/10/31/press-release-over-100000-reported-killed-in-yemen-war/#:∼:text=PRESS%20RELEASE%3A%20Over%20100%2C000%20Reported%20Killed%20in%20Yemen%20War,-Oct312019&text=31%20October%202019%3A%20The%20Armed,civilians%20killed%20in%20direct%20attacks (accessed September 11, 2020).Search in Google Scholar

Al Jazeera. 2018. UAE-Backed Group Vows to ‘Overthrow’ Yemen’s Government. Newspaper Editorial. https://www.aljazeera.com/news/2018/01/uae-backed-group-vows-overthrow-yemen-government-180122051136241.html (accessed July 8, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Alley, A. L. 2010. “The Rules of the Game: Unpacking Patronage Politics in Yemen.” Middle East Journal 64 (3): 386–9, https://doi.org/10.3751/64.3.13.Search in Google Scholar

Ardemagni, E. 2016. The Yemeni Conflict, Genealogy, Game-Changers and Regional Implications (ISPI Analysis No. 294, Italian Institute for International Political Studies, Milan). https://www.ispionline.it/sites/default/files/pubblicazioni/analisi295_ardemagni_13.04.2016.pdf (accessed July 4, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Ardemagni, E. 2017. Yemen: Regionalizzazione di una Crisi Interna [Yemen: an Internal Crisis Turned into a Regional One] (No. 78, Osservatorio di Politica Internazionale). http://www.parlamento.it/application/xmanager/projects/parlamento/file/repository/affariinternazionali/osservatorio/note/PI0078Not.pdf (accessed July 3, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Bonnefoy, L. 2009. “Deconstructing Salafism in Yemen.” CTC Sentinel 2 (2): 13–5.Search in Google Scholar

Bouchet, C. 2010. “War in Saada. From Local Insurrection to National Challenge.” Carnegie Papers Middle East Program 10: 12.10.2307/j.ctt6wpjfk.7Search in Google Scholar

Brandt, M. 2017. Tribes and Politics in Yemen: A History of the Houti Conflict. Oxford: Oxford University Press.10.1093/oso/9780190673598.001.0001Search in Google Scholar

Cederman, L.-E., N. B. Weidmann, and K. S. Gleditsch. 2011. “Horizontal Inequalities and Ethnonationalist Civil War: A Global Comparison.” The American Political Science Review 105 (3): 487.10.1017/S0003055411000207Search in Google Scholar

Cederman, L.-E., N. B. Wimmer, and B. Min. 2010. “Why Do Ethnic Groups Rebel? New Data and Analysis.” World Politics 62 (1): 104–5, https://doi.org/10.1017/S0043887109990219.Search in Google Scholar

Collier, P., and A. Hoeffler. 2004. “Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars.” Oxford Economic Papers 56 (4): 572–81.10.1093/oep/gpf064Search in Google Scholar

Day, S. 2010. The Political Challenge of Yemen’s Southern Movement, (Yemen: On the Brink – A Carnegie Paper Series, Middle East Program, No. 108: 4–5, 7, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Washington, DC). https://carnegieendowment.org/2010/03/23/political-challenge-of-yemen-s-southern-movement-pub-40411 (accessed July 2, 2018).Search in Google Scholar

de Soysa, I. 2017. Proxy Wars: Implications of Great-Power Rivalry for the Onset and Duration of Civil War, Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics, September 26. https://oxfordre.com/politics/view/10.1093/acrefore/9780190228637.001.0001/acrefore-9780190228637-e-526 (accessed June 8, 2019).10.1093/acrefore/9780190228637.013.526Search in Google Scholar

Dresch, P. 1989. Tribes, Government and History in Yemen, Vol. 3, 243–7, 219–24. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Search in Google Scholar

EIA Beta. 2019. Yemen Country Analysis Brief, last modified April 23. https://www.eia.gov/beta/international/analysis.php?iso=YEM (accessed July 6, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Esteban, J., L. Mayoral, and D. Ray. 2012. “Ethnicity and Conflict: An Empirical Study.” American Economic Review 102 (4): 1335–7.10.1257/aer.102.4.1310Search in Google Scholar

Fattah, K. 2010. “A Political History of Civil Military Relations in Yemen.” Alternative Politics, Special Issue 1: 37–43.Search in Google Scholar

Fearon, J. D., and D. D. Laitin. 2003. “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War.” American Political Science Review 97 (1): 82–6.10.1017/S0003055403000534Search in Google Scholar

Gasim, G. 2018. What is Going on in Southern Yemen?, Al Jazeera, January 29. https://www.aljazeera.com/indepth/opinion/south-yemen-secession-aden-180129095311293.html (accessed July 17, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Ghanem, A. 2019. Addressing Social Fragmentation in Yemen. Sana’a: Sana’a Center for Strategic Studies, 7. http://sanaacenter.org/publications/analysis/7137 (accessed July 3, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Ghobari, M., and M. Sudam. 2011. Protest Erupt in Yemen, President Offers Reform, Reuters, January 20. https://www.reuters.com/article/us-yemen-unrest/protests-erupt-in-yemen-president-offers-reform-idUSTRE70J58L20110120 (accessed July 9, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Gurr, T. R. 1970. Why Men Rebel. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Heras, N. A. 2018. “‘Security Belt’: The UAE’s Tribal Counterterrorism Strategy in Yemen.” Terrorism Monitor 16 (12): 7–11.Search in Google Scholar

Herrera, H., M. Morelli, and S. Nunnari. 2019. “A Theory of Power Wars.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP13917: 1–3.10.1561/100.00019136Search in Google Scholar

International Crisis Group. 2011. Breaking Point? Yemen’s Southern Question, Middle East Report No. 114, Brussels, 5–7, 23–5. https://www.crisisgroup.org/middle-east-north-africa/gulf-and-arabian-peninsula/yemen/203-saving-stockholm-agreement-and-averting-regional-conflagration-yemen (accessed July 3, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Juneau, T. 2016. “Iran’s Policy Towards the Houthis in Yemen: A Limited Return on a Modest Investment.” International Affairs 92 (3): 651–3, https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2346.12599.Search in Google Scholar

Langer, A. 2008. “Inequalities, the Political Environment and Civil Conflict: Evidence from 55 Developing Countries.” In Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: Understanding Group Violence in Multiethnic Societies, edited by F. Stewart, 163–4. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK.10.1057/9780230582729_8Search in Google Scholar

Miller, J. 1984. Yemen Reports Large Oil Discoveries, New York Times, December 21. https://www.nytimes.com/1984/12/21/business/yemen-reports-large-oil-discovery.html (accessed June 28, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Morelli, M., and D. Rohner. 2015. “Resource Concentration and Civil Wars.” Journal of Development Economics 117: 32–47, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2015.06.003.Search in Google Scholar

Mukhashaf, M. 2018. Yemen Separatists Capture Aden, Government Confined to Palace: Residents, Reuters, January 30. https://www.reuters.com/article/us-yemen-security-clashes/yemen-separatists-capture-aden-government-confined-to-palace-residents-idUSKBN1FJ17E (accessed July 8, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Mumford, A. 2013. “Proxy Warfare and the Future of Conflict.” The RUSI Journal 158 (2): 40, https://doi.org/10.1080/03071847.2013.787733.Search in Google Scholar

Østby, G. 2008. “Inequalities, the Political Environment and Civil Conflict: Evidence from 55 Developing Countries.” In Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: Understanding Group Violence in Multiethnic Societies, edited by F. Stewart, 153–4. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK.10.1057/9780230582729_7Search in Google Scholar

Perkins, B. M. 2017. The Risks of Forgetting Yemen’s Southern Secessionist Movement, War on the Rocks, March 13. https://warontherocks.com/2017/03/the-risks-of-forgetting-yemens-southern-secessionist-movement/ (accessed July 12, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Regan, P. M. 2000. Civil Wars and Foreign Powers: Outside Intervention in Intrastate Conflict. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 9.10.3998/mpub.16706Search in Google Scholar

Rosenau, J. N. 1968. “The Concept of Intervention.” Journal of International Affairs 22 (2): 167.Search in Google Scholar

Sabahi, F. 2010. Storia dello Yemen [History of Yemen], e-book ed. Milano: Mondadori, 102–5, 125–35, 143–8, 160–2.Search in Google Scholar

Salisbury, P. 2017. Yemen – National Chaos, Local Order. London: Middle East and North Africa Program, Chatham House, 8, 12, 32–3. https://www.chathamhouse.org/publication/yemen-national-chaos-local-order (accessed July 3, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Salisbury, P. 2018. Yemen’s Southern Powder Keg. London: Middle East and North Africa Program, Chatham House, 8, 10–4, 24–5. https://www.chathamhouse.org/publication/yemens-southern-powder-keg (accessed July 2, 2018).Search in Google Scholar

Salmoni, B. A., B. Loidolt, and M. Wells. 2010. Regime and Periphery in Northern Yemen: The Huthi Phenomenon, e-book ed. Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation, 25, 154, 156–7, 197–215, 236.Search in Google Scholar

Schmitz, C. 2014. The Huthi Ascent to Power. Middle East Institute, September 15. https://www.mei.edu/publications/huthi-ascent-power (accessed November 6, 2020).Search in Google Scholar

Sharp, J. M. 2019. Yemen: Civil War and Regional Intervention. Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service, 2. https://fas.org/sgp/crs/mideast/R43960.pdf (accessed July 6, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Shuja al-Deen, M. 2019. Federalism in Yemen: A Catalyst for War, the Present Reality, and the Inevitable Future. Sana’a: Sana’a Center for Strategic Studies, 4–25, 14–7. http://sanaacenter.org/files/Federalism_in_Yemen.pdf (accessed July 4, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Stewart, F. 2005. “Horizontal Inequalities: A Neglected Dimension of Development.” In Wider Perspectives on Global Development, edited by A. Shorrocks, 102. London: Palgrave Macmillan.10.1057/9780230501850_5Search in Google Scholar

Taylor, A. 2015. Who are the Houthis, the Group that just Toppled Yemen’s Government? The Washington Post, January 23. https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/worldviews/wp/2015/01/22/who-are-the-houthis-the-group-that-just-toppled-yemens-government/ (accessed November 6, 2020).Search in Google Scholar

UN Panel of Experts on Yemen. 2014. Letter Dated 22 January 2016 from the Panel of Experts on Yemen Established Pursuant to Security Council Resolution 2140 (2014) Addressed to the President of the Security Council, 24–6. https://digitallibrary.un.org/record/819771/files/S_2016_73-EN.pdf?version=1 (accessed July 10, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Wintour, P. 2017. Yemen Houthi Rebels Kill Former President Ali Abdullah Saleh, The Guardian, December 4. https://www.theguardian.com/world/2017/dec/04/former-yemen-president-saleh-killed-in-fresh-fighting (accessed July 6, 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2020-06-09
Accepted: 2020-12-02
Published Online: 2020-12-18

© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 15.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/peps-2020-0028/html
Scroll to top button