Abstract
This paper studies the practice of loss-leader pricing strategy in the English Premier League (EPL). While the TV broadcasting revenue for EPL clubs has increased over the past 20 years, the importance of revenue from ticket sales has declined. The theory of multi-product pricing suggests that a change in the relative importance of revenue sources can induce profit-maximizing firms to underprice one product in order to raise the demand for a complementary one. Using other leagues in England and Scotland that do not have as much TV broadcasting revenue as a control group, we find that inferior seats are underpriced among the EPL clubs. Consistent with the growing importance of TV broadcast revenue, we also find that such “loss-leader pricing” is stronger in later years of the sample. Furthermore, we provide evidence that the underpricing of inferior seats is more pronounced in (i) EPL clubs compared to clubs in other European leagues; (ii) elite clubs in EPL compared to non-elite clubs in EPL that have less TV broadcasting revenue; and (iii) clubs promoted to EPL as compared to clubs that are either promoted or relegated to different leagues in England and Scotland. These findings corroborate with the hypothesis that clubs that rely more on TV broadcasting underprice their inferior seats as loss leader to attract more passionate fans.
Appendix Home advantage and attendance rate
An implicit assumption in our analysis is that a higher attendance rate in a game implies stronger home advantage for the home team. Here we use the head-to-head results, attendance, and other information for all the league games in England and Scotland between 2012/13 and 2017/18 seasons to test the validity of the assumption. In particular, we run the following OLS regression:
where
Table A1 below shows that, in all specifications, a higher attendance ratio is associated with higher probability of a home win, even after controlling for the strength of the home and away teams.
Is attendance related to win probability?
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Home game outcome (win = 3, draw = 1, loss = 0) | ||||
Attendance ratio | 0.585*** | 0.355*** | 0.359*** | 0.155*** |
(14.49) | (8.61) | (7.99) | (2.76) | |
Away team controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Season FE | No | Yes | Yes | Yes |
League FE | No | No | Yes | Yes |
Home Team FE | No | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 21,361 | 21,361 | 21,361 | 21,361 |
R2 | 0.01 | 0.04 | 0.04 | 0.07 |
References
Bird, P. J. 1982. “The Demand for League Football.” Applied Economics 14 (6): 637–49, https://doi.org/10.1080/00036848200000038.Search in Google Scholar
Carron, A. V., and G. A. Agnew. 1994. “Crowd Effects and the Home Advantage.” International Journal of Sport Psychology 25 (1): 53–62.Search in Google Scholar
Cheung, S. N. S. 1977. “Why are Better Seats ‘Underpriced’?” Economic Inquiry 15: 513–22, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7295.1977.tb01114.x.Search in Google Scholar
Clarke, S. R., and J. M. Norman. 1995. “Home Ground Advantage of Individual Clubs in English Soccer.” Statistician 44 (4): 509–21, https://doi.org/10.2307/2348899.Search in Google Scholar
Courty, P. 2000. “An Economic Guide to Ticket Pricing in the Entertainment Industry.” Louvain Economic Review 66 (2): 167–92, https://doi.org/10.1017/S0770451800083858.Search in Google Scholar
DeGraba, P. 2006. “The Loss Leader is a Turkey: Targeted Discounts from Multi-Product Competitors.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 24: 613–28, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2005.08.013.Search in Google Scholar
Fort, R. 2004. “Inelastic Sports Pricing.” Managerial and Decision Economics 25: 87–94, https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1108.Search in Google Scholar
Fort, R., and J. Quirk. 1995. “Cross-Subsidization, Incentives, and Outcomes in Professional Team Sports Leagues.” Journal of Economic Literature 33 (3): 1265–99.Search in Google Scholar
Garcia, J., and P. Ridriguez. 2002. “The Determinants of Football Match Attendance Revisited: Empirical Evidence From the Spanish Football League.” Journal of Sports Economics 3 (1): 18–38, https://doi.org/10.1177/152700250200300103.Search in Google Scholar
Hess, J. D., and E. Gerstner 1987. “Loss Leader Pricing and Rain Check Policy.” Marketing Science 6 (4): 358–74, https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.6.4.358.Search in Google Scholar
Kim, J-H., and T. C. Leung. 2017. Quantifying the Impacts of Digital Rights Management and E-Book Pricing on the E-Book Reader Market. Working paper.Search in Google Scholar
Krautmann, A. C., and D. J. Berri. 2007. “Can We Find it at the Concessions? Understanding Price Elasticity in Professional Sports.” Journal of Sports Economics 8 (2): 183–91, https://doi.org/10.1177/1527002505275093.Search in Google Scholar
Krueger, A. B. 2005. “The Economics of Real Superstars: The Market for Rock Concerts in the Material World.” Journal of Labor Economics 23 (1): 1–30, https://doi.org/10.1086/425431.Search in Google Scholar
Lal, R., and C. Matutes. 1994. “Retail Pricing and Advertising Strategies.” Journal of Business 67 (3): 345–70, https://doi.org/10.1086/296637.Search in Google Scholar
Landsburgh, S. 1993. “Why Popcorn Costs More at the Movies and Why the Obvious Answer is Wrong?” In The Armchair Economist: Economics and Everyday Life, edited by S. Landsburgh, 157–67. Maxwell: Macmillan.Search in Google Scholar
Leslie, P. 2004. “Price Discrimination in Broadway Theater.” RAND Journal of Economics 35 (3): 520–41, https://doi.org/10.2307/1593706.Search in Google Scholar
Leung, T. C. 2015. “Music Piracy: Bad for Record Sales but Good for the iPod?” Information Economics and Policy 31: 1–12, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2015.04.001.Search in Google Scholar
Li, X., B. Gu, and H. Liu. 2013. “Price Dispersion and Loss-Leader Pricing: Evidence from the Online Book Industry.” Management Science 59 (6): 1290–308, https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1642.Search in Google Scholar
Lott, J. R., and R. D. Roberts. 1991. “A Guide to the Pitfalls of Identifying Price Discrimination.” Economic Inquiry 29 (1): 14–23, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7295.1991.tb01249.x.Search in Google Scholar
McManus, B. 2007. “Nonlinear Pricing in an Oligopoly Market: The Case of Specialty Coffee.” RAND Journal of Economics 38 (2): 512–32, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1756-2171.2007.tb00081.x.Search in Google Scholar
Mortimer, J. H., C. Nosko, and A. Sorensen. 2012. “Supply Responses to Digital Distribution: Recorded Music and Live Performances.” Information Economics and Policy 24: 3–14, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2012.01.007.Search in Google Scholar
Nevill, A. M., S. M. Newell, and S. Gale. 1996. “Factors Associated with Home Advantage in English and Scottish Soccer Matches.” Journal of Sports Sciences 14 (2): 181–6, https://doi.org/10.1080/02640419608727700.Search in Google Scholar
Rosen, S., and A. M. Rosenfield. 1997. “Ticket Pricing.” Journal of Law and Economics 40: 351–76, https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/abs/10.1086/467376.10.1086/467376Search in Google Scholar
Steiner, F. 1997. “Optimal Pricing of Museum Admission.” Journal of Cultural Economics 21 (4): 307–33.10.1023/A:1007432901540Search in Google Scholar
© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Original Articles
- Four Patterns in the Evolution of Dismissal and Resignation: An Epitome of the Labor Law Regime during Forty Years of Reform and Opening Up
- Why Are Inferior Seats “Underpriced”? Evidence from the English Premier League
- Corporations as the Outgroup?
- Transaction Cost and the Theory of Games: The “Prisoners’ Dilemma” as an Example
- Does Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) Promote Socioeconomic Development? Evidence from Advanced, Emerging-market, Developing and Transition Economies
- Competition
- Wisdom of the Past
- Henry Martyn on East-India Trade
Articles in the same Issue
- Original Articles
- Four Patterns in the Evolution of Dismissal and Resignation: An Epitome of the Labor Law Regime during Forty Years of Reform and Opening Up
- Why Are Inferior Seats “Underpriced”? Evidence from the English Premier League
- Corporations as the Outgroup?
- Transaction Cost and the Theory of Games: The “Prisoners’ Dilemma” as an Example
- Does Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) Promote Socioeconomic Development? Evidence from Advanced, Emerging-market, Developing and Transition Economies
- Competition
- Wisdom of the Past
- Henry Martyn on East-India Trade