Abstract
In this article we will propose a novel, self-financing, dynamic and path dependent portfolio trading strategy which is based on the well known principle “sell high – buy low”. Trading strategies are important also for the hedging problem selling/buying an option. The main problem of the writer of an option is how to invest the amount that she has received selling the option therefore the proposed trading strategy play an important role here. We will see that the hedging problem reduces to an optimization one and therefore the portfolio optimization and the hedging problem are closely related. We will also propose a deterministic portfolio selection method (i.e., without making any assumption-guess about the assets) and a notion of a deterministic fair price of an option.
1 Introduction
Assume that an investor has decided to invest the amount Y at a d different assets. The portfolio optimization problem is: how much money should the investor spend on each asset?
One way (see [16]) is to buy
We will also discuss the problem of option pricing. The existing pricing methods attempt to define the concept of the fair price of an option based on an assumption about the underlying asset. It is well known that the price of an option is formed according to the law of supply and demand, but the calculation of the fair price can be useful for investors. For example, if an investor wants to buy or sell an option with a complicated payoff function written on several underlying assets may want to calculate the fair price in order to have the order of magnitude for the value of the contract. This fair price can be used then at the trading stage.
Suppose that an investor make a guess about the future movement of
the price of the asset, i.e., for example that follows the
geometric Brownian motion with some parameters
Since existing option pricing theories are based on an assumption about the future movement of the stock, we do not expect all investors to agree on these prices. In this article we will define another notion of the fair price of an option without making an assumption about the behavior of the underlying asset. Moreover, the proposed hedging portfolio is a static one and therefore can be constructed easily by the investors.
2 A dynamic portfolio optimization method
In this section we will describe a dynamic trading strategy based
on the “sell high – buy low” (and “borrow high – return low”)
principle. Assume that an investor has decided to spend the amount
Y buying a shares of a stock borrowing the amount b from his
own bank account with risk free rate equal to r. Let also that
she has decide to reconstruct her portfolio at the times
while if
We can choose for example
for some
where
Problem 1.
Does the choice of the best function
If we take into account the transaction costs then we should find
a suitable
Suppose that at the time t the price
and when
Finally, another similar to the above trading strategy is by
setting, when
and when
At the above hedging strategy one can choose different functions δ in each case.
Therefore, at time T the value of the portfolio will be equal to, concerning for example the trading strategy (2.3) and (2.4) and taking into account the transaction costs,
The investor can buy suitable call and put options in order to
maximize her profit. Let
where
for some
The parameters
for a suitable chosen function f,
The investor may want to solve a more complicated optimization problem which is as follows:
where Δ can be of the form
for example
By solving the above optimization problem, one can construct well
known hedging strategies (see for example [8, Section
9.3]) but also more complex ones by appropriately selecting the set
A purely deterministic optimization problem that can be solved by the investor is the following:
for some
We denote by
Here
Other similar deterministic optimization problems are, for example, finding the smallest D, i.e., constructing a portfolio with the smallest possible loss, or maximizing the quantities
for a specified
One can construct an even more complicated
optimization problem by assuming that the “buy low – sell high”
strategy can be applied more often than the times
In the above optimization problems one can add more requirements such as
The requirement
All the above optimization problems should be converted to more suitable mathematical forms. Let us see some examples on this direction.
The simplest problem from a mathematical point of view seems to be the following:
The solution will be a portfolio with the least possible loss which is the value of the maxmin problem above. If the maximum possible loss of this portfolio is nonnegative, then we have an arbitrage opportunity.
If we want to add the deterministic property that
The solution will be a portfolio with the deterministic property
that
Solving the following optimization problem:
we can construct all the possible portfolios which have the
property
For a given
where
This problem will give us a portfolio (if any) with the
deterministic property that
In this spirit we can construct various optimization problems searching portfolios with deterministic properties. If there exists several portfolios with the desired properties then we can choose that one which maximizes some Δ as above.
In all the above optimization problems we set
where Y is the value of the portfolio at time zero.
Since Δ contain quantities like the probability of profit,
the investor has to make a guess about the future movement of the
price of the asset, like the geometric Brownian motion or more
complicated. The above optimization problem may be is difficult to
solve, however, since this is strongly dependent on the guess of
the investor, then one can sacrifice the accuracy of the
calculations for the sake of the computation time. We can easily
see that the quantities like the probability of profit, the mean
value of profit and so on, are functions of
where
Of course, we can compute the above quantities by doing some simulations and this will be the case if one assumes a more complicated assumption about the future movement of the price of the underlying.
Concerning the “sell high – buy low” strategy it is easy to see that the possible loss and the transaction costs are limited while the possible profit is unlimited. Comparing with the Black–Scholes hedging strategy for a call or a put option, we see that it is not satisfy the “sell high – buy low” principle, on the contrary. Moreover, the possible loss is unlimited and the transaction costs are unlimited as well!
A similar optimization problem will arise if the investor want to
construct a portfolio with d different assets, adding also call
and put options for each asset. Of course, the investor should use
a small time interval
The above portfolio management method is by far more general than
the existing ones. For example, one can choose
Setting
The above optimization problem can be converted to a stochastic optimal control problem in continuous time. Closely related works can be found in the literature, see for example [17, 18]. The advantage of our trading strategy is that it depends on the price of the asset at each time step, i.e., is path dependent, it satisfies the “buy low – sell high” principle and it also assumes that the investor will rebuild the portfolio at a discrete time.
3 Option pricing and the Black–Scholes model
In this section we will discuss the option pricing problem.
Consider for example the well-known Black–Scholes option pricing
model (see [5]) for a call option which pays the holder the
amount
and
then to compute the initial value of a replicating portfolio,
i.e., a portfolio which contain
So, it is not possible to construct the Black–Scholes hedging strategy in continuous time but only approximately in discrete time. Concerning the expiration time T (for example three months) we should transform it to actively hours in which we can make any trade we want. How often we have to reconstruct this hedging portfolio? Can we estimate the probability of profit, the mean value and the variance of profit, assuming that the underlying asset follows the geometric Brownian motion? The possible loss is unlimited or not? If the possible loss is unlimited, can we design a similar hedging strategy by using call options with different strike prices and/or maybe with different expiration dates? Note that the parameter σ at the assumption (3.1) is not a universal constant and the investors do not agree on a specific price. If someone uses historical data of six months, he/she will get a different value using historical data of one year and so on. Using the notion of the implied volatility has no meaning for the pricing problem but only for the hedging problem as we will explain below!
Here, we should distinguish the asset pricing model that the Black–Scholes theory use from the asset pricing model that the investor use to guess the future movement of the price of the underlying asset. That is, in order to compute the Black–Scholes hedging strategy we should make an assumption about the asset price, like the geometric Brownian motion, Heston model, etc. Note that by using a different assumption for the asset price we arrive at a different Black–Scholes-type hedging strategy, that is, we have a whole family of Black–Scholes strategies choosing a different model. We call this asset pricing model as the embedded asset pricing model. In order to compute the parameters of the embedded asset pricing model we should first decide how much money we want to spend on this hedging strategy. Suppose that the investor decides to use the amount Y, then she should find the implied parameters which are such that the initial value of the Black–Scholes replicating portfolio equals Y. This is a calibration of the imbedded asset pricing model which is a totally different notion than the calibration suggested by [10], for example.
Obviously, in order to find the implied parameters of the imbedded asset pricing model one should assume a fairly simple model, like the geometric Brownian motion. The investor can make a guess about the future movement of the price of the asset which may be different from the imbedded asset pricing model. We call this asset pricing model as the external asset pricing model. In order to compute the parameters of the external asset pricing model, the investor should use historical data and her intuition. That is, the notion of the implied parameters has a meaning only for the imbedded asset pricing model while the historical (or other) data and information has a meaning only for the computation of the parameters of the external asset pricing model.
We arrive at the following corollary.
Corollary 1.
We cannot define a unique fair price for an option by using the Black–Scholes theory or any similar theory that use forecasting techniques. Any attempt to define a fair price or a unique arbitrage free price will not be well defined in practice if it is based on an assumption about the future price movement of the underlying asset! Therefore the computation of the initial value of this replicating portfolio, given the parameters of the imbedded pricing model, has no meaning in practice. In fact, the inverse mathematical problem has a practical meaning, i.e., given an amount Y, compute the implied parameters of the chosen imbedded pricing model so that the initial value of this replicating portfolio equal to Y. Having the implied parameters of the imbedded pricing model, we can compute the hedging strategy that one should follow using the amount Y, which is exactly what the investor need to know.
Using probabilistic techniques is equivalent to forecasting, therefore the notion of the fair price is not well defined under this point of view. In this spirit the authors of [3] have try to overcome this difficulty describing option pricing models without probability. However, again the hedging portfolio should be reconstructed continuously in time.
Concerning the well-known put-call parity formula one can easily observe that it is not satisfied in reality, mainly, because of the following two reasons. The first reason is the risk free rate which is not a universal constant and each investor can invest/borrow at a different rate while the second reason are the transaction costs. Therefore the put-call parity cannot be used in order to compute the price of the put knowing the price of the call. Note also that each of them are known at time zero while each of them are unknown in the future. However, the put-call parity formula can be used by the arbitrageurs (applying their own risk free rate) in order to make profit without risk.
4 Hedging strategies
Suppose that the writer wants to use the amount Y (not
necessarily the price of the option) in order to construct the
hedging portfolio suggested by the Black–Scholes theory with the
geometric Brownian motion as the embedded pricing model. Then she
has to compute the implied volatility
A different hedging strategy is to choose two possible prices
This conclusion holds without assuming anything about the behavior
of the price of the underlying asset. If the writer wants to
compute the probability of profit, then she must assume something
like the geometric Brownian motion for the underlying, i.e., to
make an external asset pricing assumption. This hedging strategy
can be applied in the real world and in fact the writer bets on
the event
Another hedging strategy is to choose some
We can design also other hedging strategies that can be applied in the real world. The writer must decide which is the most appropriate for her case.
Example 1 (Black–Scholes vs.
γ
+
1
hedging strategy).
Let the writer sell a call option at the price Y. She decides to
use two hedging strategies: the first one is the Black–Scholes
hedging strategy with the geometric Brownian motion as the
imbedded asset pricing model and the second is the
with
where
Note that the term
Example 2 (Binomial vs.
γ
+
1
hedging strategy).
Let the writer of a call option with price Y and strike price
K decide to use the realistic binomial hedging strategy. In
order to eliminate the risk of bankruptcy, she can buy another call
option with strike price
where
and
So, what is the most suitable hedging strategy among the binomial
and
where
In order to solve the above problem, we should convert it to a
more suitable form. Let us assume that
Another construction can be done by solving the following
deterministic mathematical problem: given the price Y, find the
smallest
Since this function is piecewise linear, the above mathematical problem can be converted to the following:
We require
If the underlying asset
Example 3 (Multi-asset options).
Let an option with payoff
where
Here, by
Example 4 (A path dependent option).
Let an option written on one underlying asset with payoff
where
The
question here is how to hedge such an option selling at the price Y. Can we design a hedging strategy with limited possible loss?
Yes, we can, however with a big possible loss. One can buy N
assets borrowing the amount b and sell some of them at each time
What can we do in the case where there is not available such a
series of call options? A way is to use a dynamic hedging
strategy, that is, we buy a shares of the underlying at time zero
borrowing the amount b, and at the times
Example 5 (A basket option).
Let
for
some
The profit function here is the following two-variables function:
We denote by
We can compute the fair price of this type of option by solving two similar linear programming problems. The notion of the fair price will be introduced in Section 5.2.
Example 6 (Portfolio management).
Suppose that an investor want to invest the amount V on two assets and suppose that there exists in the market one call and one put option for each asset. Then the investor can construct the portfolio
where
The profit function is
One way to choose a portfolio is by solving a linear programming
problem in order to find the smallest D for which the profit
function will be greater than D for all
(4.1)
for some
or solve the optimization problem
Another way is to look for all possible portfolios with the
property
We can think a lot of this kind of deterministic problems. The investor can add more call and put options so that she can find more portfolios that meets these properties.
Note that problem (4.1) is purely deterministic, i.e., the investor do not need to make any assumption or prediction about the underlying assets. This is an advantage in contrast to the Markowitz (see [16]) portfolio selection theory and all the similar theories in which the investor should at first make a guess about the assets.
If there are more than one portfolios that meets all the desired deterministic properties, the investor can make a guess about the distribution of each asset and then choose that portfolio which maximize an expression like the following:
for some
It is clear that the information about these deterministic properties are very useful for the investor while the information which depends on the distribution of the each asset is not. The reason is that the probability measure is not universally accepted and is a personal guess.
In all the above proposed optimization problems we can add call and put options with different expiration dates and of course we can add any other type of options that the investor can buy or sell.
5 Arbitrage and fair price of an option
5.1 Arbitrage
As we have seen, an arbitrageur can use the put-call parity to find an arbitrage opportunity. Below we will describe also another way buying or selling a contract.
Suppose that an investor has sell a contract at the price Y and
suppose that with the amount
In general, we can search for an arbitrage opportunity by finding
a portfolio with
In order to search for an arbitrage opportunity concerning only one asset we can solve the following linear programming problem:
where Y is the amount that we want to invest. Here
We
can choose some
If we want to construct a portfolio which will be profitable if
In the case where we want
5.2 Fair price of an option
As we have discussed, the notion of the fair price of an option has no meaning in practice if this depends on an assumption about the future movement of the underlying asset. Let us give a theoretical example. In a fair dice we can define a probability measure and based on this we can come to some conclusions. The same can be done on a dice that is not fair but has a specific preference for certain outcomes. Now consider a dice which is sometimes fair and sometimes not. The time when it changes behavior is also random. When it is not fair it changes preferences also randomly. On such a dice it is not wise to define a probability measure. This is precisely the case in Financial and Actuarial Mathematics. Even if you do define a probability measure, it will be a personal prediction which is certainly not generally accepted by other investors and therefore any conclusion will be purely personal and can be used only for forecasting reasons.
Below we will discuss the notion of the fair price of an option but without assuming something about the future movement of the underlying asset.
As we have discussed both the buyer and the writer of an option
can (try to) construct a portfolio which contain this option and
also other assets or options so that
where
The buyer can construct a portfolio with profit at time T as follows:
where
Defining the functions
we are in a position to define the set
The set
Definition 1 (Fair price of an option).
We define the fair price of an option to be the
unique element of the set
The fair price as we have define it
above is a function of the two risk free assets
The set
There are also some other criteria that if the above fair price meets then this notion is stronger. Below we propose some possible criteria for this purpose:
We can propose another criteria as well but these has to be independent of the distribution of the price of the underlying asset so that they are universally accepted.
The fair price and the properties of the “fair portfolios” are functions of the prices of the asset and all the call and puts a mathematical problem arise. What should these prices preserve so that the fair price is strong enough?
The above definition depends on deterministic properties of the two static portfolios which can be constructed in practice, in contrast to the Black–Scholes hedging portfolios. The investors do not need to make any assumption about the future movement of the underlying asset. However, one should take into account the transaction costs in the above computations but the idea is the same.
Remark 2.
Suppose that we want to price a call option with strike price K applying the Black–Scholes theory. How do we calculate the volatility?
If there are already some call options with strike prices
However, this is generally not the case since this theory does not take into account the prices of existing call options.
On the contrary, the option pricing theory that we have proposed will certainly give a reasonable price for this call option since it takes into account the values of call options already existing in the market.
As one can see, we have included all the call and put options with expiration dates until time T. Therefore, the profit function is a function of t also. This can help us to calculate a fair price for Bermudan type of options in which the buyer can exercise the option only at these dates. The same also holds for path dependent options for which the payoff is calculated concerning only the expiration dates of the call and put options. This will be also a problem of a future study.
We can define also other, similar, deterministic fair prices. Setting
we can define the set
which has at most one element. In this case we define this element as the fair price of the option.
Setting
we can define the set
which has also at most one element. Since
In the market we will not often see options sold at the above fair prices because the price is determined according to the law of supply and demand. Therefore we should not confuse the notion of the fair price of an option with the problem of forecasting the future price of an option because this depend on the behavior of the investors. In this spirit, the notion of the implied volatility in the Black–Scholes theory has no meaning. The implied volatility, as we have discussed, has a meaning only if the investor could indeed construct the proposed portfolio!
Even if a contract is sold at any of the above fair prices, the investor can still choose any other hedging portfolio that is profitable in some eventuality that he or she foresees will occur. He can also make a guess about the distribution of the corresponding random variable and according to this guess choose the appropriate portfolio but with an initial value of the selling price Y. We have discussed all these at the previous sections.
By calculating the fair value of a contract in the above way, the investor will know the order of magnitude of the value of that contract. Based on this information, the bargaining for the purchase and sale of the contract can begin.
For multi-asset options the idea is exactly the same however the mathematical problem is much more complicated. We will see in Example 4 how we can compute a fair price for a basket option.
Let us now state an open and interesting problem regarding the fair value as we have proposed above.
Problem 2.
Suppose that there is only one call and one put in
the market with the same underlying asset. Suppose that the writer
has sold a contract with this underlying asset. Then one can
compute the fair price of the contract as we have proposed and
suppose that this is the
Now, suppose that there exists one more call and one more put
options in the market and we compute again the fair value of the
option which is
The question is how the fair value behaves as we add more and more
call and put options and what options make the biggest difference,
these with strike price near
Another question is what the prices of the call and put options should preserve in order to be able to find a fair value of a specific option. If we want this fair value to be stronger (requiring more properties for the “fair portfolios”) what properties should the values preserve?
What other deterministic criteria can be used to define a fair price of an option? In the case where all the deterministic fair prices are equal then of course this price is universally accepted. What should the today prices of the assets and the corresponding call and put options should preserve so that all the deterministic fair prices are equal?
We have proposed some notions of deterministic fair prices but as one can see we can also propose any combination of the above. For example, by minimizing a quantity like the following:
How the fair price changes as we change the definition? For
example, let
and what are the properties of this function?
By the above discussion we understand that there is not any notion for a unique fair price but also we understand that any notion of fair price should be given under deterministic arguments. Concerning the above deterministic fair prices we do not expect that will be (exactly) equal to each other but we expect to have the same order of magnitude which is exactly what the investor want to know before the bargaining stage. Another useful information is the mean and variance of the historical payoffs of this option. How this mean and variance related with the deterministic fair prices?
Consider now the following minimization problem:
How are the initial values of these minimizing portfolios related with the proposed fair values?
Example 3 (Fair price of a call).
Suppose that
We will find the fair price using the above definition. This fair price Y will be the price which both the writer and the buyer can construct portfolios with the same maximum possible loss.
For a given price Y solving the following linear programming problem we will find the portfolio for the writer with the minimum possible loss D. The problem is
where
Similarly, for a given price Y we will find the portfolio for the buyer with the minimum possible loss D by solving the following problem:
where
For
while the buyer a portfolio with the profit function
It is easy to see that the minimum of both the above two profit
functions is the number -0.31 while both tend to
It is clear that if the writer sell this option at a price bigger than 0.25, then she can construct a portfolio with less maximum possible loss while the buyer with bigger maximum possible loss.
Concerning the Black–Scholes fair price, the two parties should agree at first on the volatility. Secondly, the writer should be able to construct this portfolio which is not the case as we have already discussed. For the binomial, trinomial model, etc., the two parties should agree that the possible values of the underlying is only two, three, etc., and moreover agree at the values of the rates.
Example 4 (Fair price of a basket option).
Let us return to Example 5. We will describe below how to compute a fair price of this option.
As we have described the writer of the option can construct a hedging portfolio, using the amount Y, by solving the following linear programming problem:
The profit function here is the following two-variables function:
Similarly, the buyer can construct a hedging portfolio by solving the following linear programming problem:
The profit function here is the following two-variables function:
In order to find the fair price Y of this basket option, we should find the unique Y for which both the writer and the buyer can construct hedging portfolios with the same maximum possible loss D.
By finding the above fair price, both the writer and the buyer will have in their hands a realizable hedge portfolio. They will also know the order of magnitude of the value of this option and this can be used at the trading stage.
Of course, by selling or buying this option at a price of Y, the investors can use this amount to construct a hedge portfolio as they wish.
The investors can compute also other deterministic fair prices of this option concerning different criteria. It is interesting to find also other deterministic criteria in order to define different fair values and see how these prices changes from each other.
Is there a possibility to design a perfect hedging strategy for an option containing all the put and call options of the underlying assets? Suppose that we want to design such a hedging strategy in discrete time for which the final value of the portfolio equal to the payoff of an option with one underlying asset. Namely, we want to design a hedging strategy of the following kind:
Then using this hedging strategy we should have
for any
6 Conclusion
In this note we have proposed a dynamic and path dependent trading strategy based on the principle “sell high – buy low” which can be used also to hedge the risk selling an option.
We discussed also the option pricing problem and we came to the conclusion that this problem does not exist in practice. The question for the writer of an option is how she will use the amount received to hedge the risk. Therefore, the question is: what is the most effective hedging strategy for each case? We have given the notion of the imbedded and external asset pricing assumption (in the Black–Scholes setting) and see that the notion of the implied parameters have a meaning only for the imbedded asset pricing model.
We find out that the portfolio optimization problem is closely
related with the hedging problem. In all the above considerations
crucial role will play the guess of the investor, i.e., what model
and with what parameters to use for the price of the underlying or
even a guess about a set
In this work we have included deterministic properties for the
problem of the selection of the portfolio, such as that the
profit should be greater than
For a complicated contract, the investors at first, need to know the mean and the variance of the historical payoffs (see [14] for a closely related study) while the price of this contract will be shaped by the law of supply and demand. In this stage any deterministic fair price will be also useful for the investors because they will have the order of magnitude of the value of this contract and of course because the accompanied hedging portfolios can be practically constructed.
If the investor’s guess about the future movement of the price of the asset involves a complicated stochastic differential equation, then the computations may need a numerical approach. In this direction the numerical scheme should preserve the positivity property of the true solution, see for example [13] and the references therein.
Finally, we have discussed the notion of the (deterministic) fair price which seems that it is very important to theoretical financial analysts! The fair price of an option as we have described above will be the study of a future research since it seems that is the first attempt to define the notion of a fair value using deterministic and thus universally accepted arguments. As we have seen, there several notions of deterministic fair prices therefore this notion can be used purely for personal reasons, for example in order to find the order of magnitude of the value of the contract, an information that can be used to the bargaining stage. The computation of any fair price should be done using only deterministic arguments. The same holds also for the problem of transferring the risk, i.e., the hedging problem. It has no meaning to transfer risk with some probability! On the other hand, for the forecasting problem, i.e., what is the future price of an asset or a contract, one should use statistics and stochastic analysis, behavioral finance, machine learning, etc.
References
[1] H. Albrecher, J. Beirlant and J. L. Teugels, Reinsurance: Actuarial and Statistical Aspects, Wiley Ser. Probab. Stat., John Wiley & Sons, Hoboken, 2017. 10.1002/9781119412540Search in Google Scholar
[2] G. Appa, On the uniqueness of solutions to linear programs, J. Oper. Res. Soc. 53 (2002), no. 10, 1127–1132. 10.1057/palgrave.jors.2601320Search in Google Scholar
[3] J. Armstrong, C. Bellani, D. Brigo and T. Cass, Option pricing models without probability: A rough paths approach, Math. Finance 31 (2021), no. 4, 1494–1521. 10.1111/mafi.12308Search in Google Scholar
[4] M. Avellaneda, A. Levy and A. Paras, Pricing and hedging derivative securities in markets with uncertain volatilities, Appl. Math. Finance 2 (1995), no. 2, 73–88. 10.1080/13504869500000005Search in Google Scholar
[5] F. Black and M. Scholes, The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, J. Polit. Econ. 81 (1973), no. 3, 637–654. 10.1086/260062Search in Google Scholar
[6] V. Capasso and D. Bakstein, An Introduction to Continuous-Time Stochastic Processes—Theory, Models, and Applications to Finance, Biology, and Medicine, Model. Simul. Sci. Eng. Technol., Birkhäuser/Springer, Cham, 2021. 10.1007/978-3-030-69653-5_2Search in Google Scholar
[7] M. Capinski and E. Kopp, Portfolio Theory and Risk Management, Cambridge University, Cambridge, 2014. 10.1017/CBO9781139017398Search in Google Scholar
[8] M. Capiński and T. Zastawniak, Mathematics for Finance, Springer Undergrad. Math. Ser., Springer, London, 2003. Search in Google Scholar
[9] P. Carr, K. Ellis and V. Gupta, Static hedging of exotic options, J. Finance 53 (1998), no. 3, 1–26. 10.1111/0022-1082.00048Search in Google Scholar
[10] R. Cont, Model calibration, Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance, Wiley, New York (2010), https://doi.org/10.1002/9780470061602.eqf08002. 10.1002/9780470061602.eqf08002Search in Google Scholar
[11] J. C. Cox, S. A. Ross and M. Rubinstein, Option pricing: A simplified approach, J. Financ. Econ. 7 (1979), no. 3, 229–263. 10.1016/0304-405X(79)90015-1Search in Google Scholar
[12] N. El Karoui, M. Jeanblanc-Picqué and S. E. Shreve, Robustness of the Black and Scholes formula, Math. Finance 8 (1998), no. 2, 93–126. 10.1111/1467-9965.00047Search in Google Scholar
[13] N. Halidias, On the construction of boundary preserving numerical schemes, Monte Carlo Methods Appl. 22 (2016), no. 4, 277–289. 10.1515/mcma-2016-0113Search in Google Scholar
[14] N. Halidias, On the practical point of view of option pricing, Monte Carlo Methods Appl. 28 (2022), no. 4, 307–318. 10.1515/mcma-2022-2122Search in Google Scholar
[15] N. Halidias, Option pricing: Examples and open problems, Monte Carlo Methods Appl. 30 (2024), no. 1, 1–17. 10.1515/mcma-2023-2014Search in Google Scholar
[16] H. M. Markowitz, Portfolio selection, J. Finance 7 (1952), 77–91. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525.xSearch in Google Scholar
[17] R. C. Merton, Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous-time model, Rev. Econ. Stat. 51 (1969), 247–257. 10.2307/1926560Search in Google Scholar
[18] R. C. Merton, Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time model, J. Econom. Theory 3 (1971), no. 4, 373–413. 10.1016/0022-0531(71)90038-XSearch in Google Scholar
[19] R. Velu, M. Hardy and D. Nehren, Algorithmic Trading and Quantitative Strategies, CRC Press, Boca Raton, 2020. 10.1201/9780429183942Search in Google Scholar
© 2024 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Joint application of the Monte Carlo method and computational probabilistic analysis in problems of numerical modeling with data uncertainties
- Another hybrid conjugate gradient method as a convex combination of WYL and CD methods
- Random walk algorithms for solving nonlinear chemotaxis problems
- A novel portfolio optimization method and its application to the hedging problem
- Dynamics of a multigroup stochastic SIQR epidemic model
- Optimal oversampling ratio in two-step simulation
- The slice sampler and centrally symmetric distributions
- Simulation of doubly stochastic Poisson point processes and application to nucleation of nanocrystals and evaluation of exciton fluxes
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Joint application of the Monte Carlo method and computational probabilistic analysis in problems of numerical modeling with data uncertainties
- Another hybrid conjugate gradient method as a convex combination of WYL and CD methods
- Random walk algorithms for solving nonlinear chemotaxis problems
- A novel portfolio optimization method and its application to the hedging problem
- Dynamics of a multigroup stochastic SIQR epidemic model
- Optimal oversampling ratio in two-step simulation
- The slice sampler and centrally symmetric distributions
- Simulation of doubly stochastic Poisson point processes and application to nucleation of nanocrystals and evaluation of exciton fluxes