Home Macroeconomic Policy Coordination in a Competitive Real Exchange Rate Strategy for Development
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Macroeconomic Policy Coordination in a Competitive Real Exchange Rate Strategy for Development

  • Martin Rapetti EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: March 27, 2013

Abstract

Recent research has documented a positive relationship between real exchange rate (RER) levels and economic growth in developing countries. The literature has interpreted this correlation as causality running from RER levels to growth rates; i.e., more competitive RER levels tend to favor growth. Little effort has been made, however, on the analysis of the policy instruments required to implement a successful competitive RER strategy. An exchange rate policy targeting a permanent change in the RER may run into difficulties: it is well documented that nominal and real exchange rate movements are correlated almost one for one in the short run but such co-movement vanishes in the long run. Targeting instead a transitory RER undervaluation can have long-lasting effects on economic performance if RER competitiveness is stable and durable enough to provide incentives for modern tradable activities to expand. The ability to provide such an environment may be beyond the scope of exchange rate policy. This paper aims to shed light on the complementary policies that facilitate the success of an exchange rate policy that temporarily increases competitiveness. A formal model is developed to analyze these issues. The main conclusion is that a currency depreciation is more likely to accelerate growth if it is simultaneously implemented with domestic demand management policies that prevent non-tradable price inflation and wage management policies that coordinate wage increases with tradable productivity growth.


Corresponding author: Martin Rapetti, CEDES and University of Buenos Aires, Argentina

Appendix

A Derivation of the =0 locus

From (22), there would be no tendency towards changes in wages and therefore =0 (i.e., the labor market would be in “equilibrium”) when:

We know that , thus to derive the shape of =0, we need first to obtain that of the locus. This requires that

Equation (14) establishes that X depends positively on K and negatively on ωT. Equation (18) states that the “bargained” real wage rate is a positive function of the employment rate lLT+LN. Equation (4) indicates that LT increases with K and diminishes with ωT. Similarly, equations (7) and (14) imply that LN increases with K and shrinks with ωT. As a result, the “bargained” real wage varies positively with K and negatively with ωT; i.e., ωK∂ω/∂K>0 and ωωK∂ω/∂ωT<0. Equation (26) can thus be expressed as an implicit function of K, ωT and the policy variables sg and z

Given that XK>0, Xωt<0, ωK>0 and ωωT<0, then the locus is positively sloped in the ωT-K space

Therefore, the =0 locus is also positively sloped in the ωT-K space. In the important case of multiple equilibria – whose conditions are derived in appendix B – it is straightforward to see that the =0 locus lies in between of the and =0 loci as described in Figure 8.

Figure 8 Benchmark phase diagram.
Figure 8

Benchmark phase diagram.

B Existence of Multiple Equilibria

The existence of multiple equilibria occurs when the and =0 loci intersect more than once. The =0 locus is obtained by setting r defined by equation (16) equal to i. Taking natural logs and differentiating totally yields

Equation (29) indicates that the =0 locus is a positively sloped straight line in the lnωT-ln K space.

A necessary condition for the multiple intersections of the two loci is that the locus in the ln ωT-ln K space has a lower slope than the =0 locus for some values of K and a higher one for some other set of values of K.

To obtain the slope of the locus in the ln ωT-ln K space, we need to substitute equations (14) and (18) into expression (26), take natural log to the resulting expression and differentiate it totally. With a little of algebra manipulation this yields

As with expression (28), the one above is also positive. Its value, however, is not constant but critically depends on the evolution of l/(1−l) as K varies. Using equations (4), (7) and (14), it is clear that l/(1−l)→∞ as K→∞ and l/(1−l)→0 as K→0.

When K→∞,

The slope of the locus is greater than that of the =0 locus if only if

When K→0

Given condition (32), the slope of the locus is lower than that of the =0 locus if

The existence of multiple equilibria requires condition (32) to hold. This implies that the positive external effects in the production of tradables need to be moderate, otherwise the productivity gains arising from learning by doing would be so large that the resulting profitability incentives for capital accumulation would be unbounded. The left-hand side of condition (34) is the slope of the =0 locus [i.e., equation (29)]. This condition thus implies that for the two loci to intersect at low levels of K, the required reaction of ωT to changes in K to reach a stationary level of K has to be higher than the rises of ωT associated to the increases in the price of non-tradables when K expands. Condition (34) is more likely to hold the higher the values of α, β and μ; i.e., the more capital intensive the tradable production, the more elastic the supply of non-tradables and the higher the share of tradables in private consumption. Conditions (32) and (34) are empirically plausible and can both hold simultaneously. Assuming such a case implies that, similarly to Ros and Skott (1998), the two loci intersect twice, once when they are tangent one to another or do not intersect.

  1. 1I want to thank the comments of two anonymous referees, Robert Blecker, Arslan Razmi, Roberto Frenkel and Daniel Aromi. I am specially grateful to Peter Skott for his encouragement and insightful suggestions. The usual disclaimers apply.

  2. 2See, among others, Hausmann et al. (2005), Prasad et al. (2007), Gala (2008), Rodrik (2008), Rapetti et al. (2012) and Bereau et al. (2012).

  3. 3I follow the definition of nominal exchange rate as the domestic price of a foreign currency. Consequently, a higher RER implies a more competitive, depreciated or undervalued domestic currency in real terms.

  4. 4This idea resembles the view of classical development economics that conceived manufactures as the engine of economic development. Agriculture and services were seen as the backward sectors. These days, there is a recognition that modern activities are comprised not only by manufactures but also by some highly productive tradable services (Rodrik 2010).

  5. 5Another common objection regards the global implications of this strategy, which are not discussed here.

  6. 6Chile’s experience fulfills the of-cited definition of growth acceleration episode developed by Hausmann et al. (2005). Argentina’s also fits this definition for the period 2003–2011.

  7. 7For an analysis of these experiences, see Frenkel and Rapetti (2012).

  8. 8An increase in tradable profitability can be achieved or strengthened with sectoral policies such as subsidized credits, tax exceptions, direct subsidies, infrastructure building and other conventional industrial and trade policies. Most successful development experiences used these instruments extensively (Rodrik 1995). Since the 1980s, however, they gradually lost mainstream appeal as the critics pointed to information problems, rent-seeking and government failures. Their use has also been threatened by WTO regulations. Without implying any judgment, in this paper I ignore the role of these policies and focus exclusively on the RER.

  9. 9A devaluation can certainly have contractionary effects in the short-run (Frankel 2005). In the case they exist, once digested, the expansive effects described above are assumed to prevail.

  10. 10Investment is mostly dominated by expected profitability (although actual profitability may also play a relevant role when firms face credit constraints). Consequently, expectations about the future are crucial for investment decisions. The view I adopt about the way agents form expectations is rather “behavioralist.” Future is by its own nature unknown. Besides, agents face costs at gathering information and have limited cognitive abilities to process the information at their dispose. In such contexts, past and present conditions could be reasonable guides to form expectations about the future. Thus, if the RER competitiveness incentive has been stable and lasted long enough, it would likely induce tradable firms to invest.

  11. 11Although a key input, labor is not the only one influencing supply conditions of non-tradables. Infrastructure, energy and land may be other relevant factors. For simplicity, I will ignore the possibility that these factors may constrain the supply of non-tradables.

  12. 12Given the assumptions that non-tradable productivity is constant and tradable productivity is catching up due to the accumulation of capital, technology and knowledge, this tendency towards RER appreciation resembles the Balassa-Samuelson effect.

  13. 13For an analysis of the conditions under which sterilized FX interventions are sustainable see Frenkel (2007). See Ocampo (2003) on the effectiveness of capital controls in developing countries.

  14. 14For simplicity I use the product wage as a proxy of unit costs, which would also include non-tradable goods. Since the determination of nominal wages are arguably influenced by the evolution of non-tradable prices, as modeled in the next section, the product wage captures the set of relative prices that are relevant to determine tradable sector’s profitability.

  15. 15The product wage is calculated as the nominal wage rate divided the exchange rate; i.e., domestic wages measured in US dollars. For tradable labor productivity, I use real GDP per capita as a proxy.

  16. 16This, in turn, is achieved by setting θ=1, θ<1 and θ>1, respectively.

  17. 17The domestic interest rate, i, could influence the behavior of private savings. However, since it is given by the international interest rate, s appears in the model as a parameter. As discussed in Section 2, the government could use sterilized interventions and capital management techniques to regain some control over monetary policy. In that case, it could manage i within a certain range and thus influence the evolution of the price of non-tradables through s. In other words, demand management policies would also include monetary policy. Although governments targeting competitive RER levels actually use a combination of policies to have some autonomy in conducting monetary policy, I will ignore this possibility to keep the algebra simple. However, s could be thought as a variable potentially influenced by monetary policy and other saving incentives offered by the government.

  18. 18The price of non-tradables also falls when private saving rate, s, rises; i.e., Xs<0. Thus, in cases in which governments have some autonomy to conduct monetary policy, a rise in the domestic interest rate would increase s and thus reduce the price of non-tradables (i.e., ↓ X).

  19. 19Two other alternatives are possible. In one case the nullclines do not intersect and in the other they are tangential to each other at a single point. None of these cases are of economic interest.

  20. 20See, for instance, Galindo and Ros (2008) for the case of Mexico and Barbosa-Filho (2008) for the case of Brazil.

References

Barbosa-Filho, N. (2008) “Ination Targeting in Brazil: 1999–2006,” International Review of Applied Economics, 22(2):187–200.10.1080/02692170701880684Search in Google Scholar

Bereau, S., A. Lopez Villavicencio and V. Mignon (2012) “Currency Misalignments and Growth: A New Look Using Nonlinear Panel Data Methods,” Applied Economics, 44(27):3503–3511.10.1080/00036846.2011.577022Search in Google Scholar

Blanchower, D. and A. Oswald (1994) The Wage Curve. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Blanchower, D. and A. Oswald (2005) The Wage Curve Reloaded. NBER Working Paper No. 11338. Cambridge, MA.10.3386/w11338Search in Google Scholar

Eichengreen, B. (2007) The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Growth. Working Paper No. 4, Commission on Growth and Development. Washington, DC.Search in Google Scholar

Frankel, J. (2005) “Contractionary Currency Crashes in Developing Countries,” IMF Staff Papers, 52(2):149–192.Search in Google Scholar

Frenkel, R. (2007) “The Sustainability of Monetary Sterilization Policies,” Cepal Review, (93):29–36.10.18356/e940ecd8-enSearch in Google Scholar

Frenkel, R. (2008) “The Competitive Real Exchange-Rate Regime, Ination and Monetary Policy,” Cepal Review, (96):191–201.10.18356/24066724-enSearch in Google Scholar

Frenkel, R. and M. Rapetti (2012) “Exchange Rate Regimes in the Major Latin American Countries since the 1950s: Lessons from History,” Revista de Historia Economica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History, 30(1):157–188.10.1017/S0212610911000292Search in Google Scholar

Gala, P. (2008) “Real Exchange Rate Levels and Economic Development: Theoretical Analysis and Econometric Evidence,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(2):273–288.10.1093/cje/bem042Search in Google Scholar

Galindo, L. and J. Ros (2008) “Alternatives to Ination Targeting in Mexico,” International Review of Applied Economics, 22(2):201–214.10.1080/02692170701880718Search in Google Scholar

Hausmann, R., L. Pritchett and D. Rodrik (2005) “Growth Accelerations,” Journal of Economic Growth, 10(4):303–329.10.1007/s10887-005-4712-0Search in Google Scholar

Korinek, A. and L. Serven (2010) Real Exchange Rate Undervaluation: Static Losses, Dynamic Gains. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 5250. Washington, DC.Search in Google Scholar

Krugman, P. (1987) “The Narrow Moving Band, the Dutch Disease, and the Competitive Consequences of Mrs. Thatcher,” Journal of Development Economics, 27(1–2):41–55.10.1016/0304-3878(87)90005-8Search in Google Scholar

Lewis, W. A. (1954) “Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour,” The Manchester School, 22(2):139–191.10.1111/j.1467-9957.1954.tb00021.xSearch in Google Scholar

Ocampo, J. A. (2003) Capital-Account and Counter-Cyclical Prudential Regulations in Developing Countries. ECLAC. Santiago, Chile.10.1057/9781403990099_12Search in Google Scholar

Porcile, G. and G. T. Lima (2010) “Real Exchange Rate and Elasticity of Labour Supply in a Balance-of-Payments-Constrained Macrodynamics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 34(6):1019–1039.10.1093/cje/bep065Search in Google Scholar

Prasad, E. S., R. G. Rajan and A. Subramanian (2007) “Foreign Capital and Economic Growth,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:153–209.10.1353/eca.2007.0016Search in Google Scholar

Rapetti, M., P. Skott and A. Razmi (2012) “The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Growth: Are Developing Countries Special?” International Review of Applied Economics, 26(6): 735–753.10.1080/02692171.2012.686483Search in Google Scholar

Razmi, A., M. Rapetti and P. Skott (2012) “The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Development,” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 23(2):151–169.10.1016/j.strueco.2012.01.002Search in Google Scholar

Rees, A. (1993) “The Role of Fairness in Wage Determination,” Journal of Labor Economics, 11(1):243–252.10.1086/298325Search in Google Scholar

Rodrik, D. (1995) “Trade and Industrial Policy Reform.” In: Handbook of Development Economics, vol. 3, pp. 2925–2982. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier.10.1016/S1573-4471(95)30022-8Search in Google Scholar

Rodrik, D. (2008) “The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Growth,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:365–412.Search in Google Scholar

Rodrik, D. (2010) “Growth After the Crisis,” In: (M. Spence and D. Leipziger, eds.,) Globalization and Growth: Implications for a Post-crisis World, Commission on Growth and Development. Washington, DC. 125.Search in Google Scholar

Ros, J. and P. Skott (1998) “Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization and Currency Overvaluation Under Conditions of Increasing Returns,” The Manchester School, 66(4):466–489.10.1111/1467-9957.00118Search in Google Scholar

Taylor, A. and M. P. Taylor (2004) “The Purchasing Power Parity Debate,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(4):135–158.10.1257/0895330042632744Search in Google Scholar

Taylor, M., D. Peel and L. Sarno (2001) “Nonlinear Mean-Reversion in Real Exchange Rates: Toward a Solution to the Purchasing Power Parity Puzzles,” International Economic Review, 42(4):1015–1042.10.1111/1468-2354.00144Search in Google Scholar

Zhang, X., J. Yang and S. Wang (2011) “China has Reached the Lewis Turning Point,” China Economic Review, 22(4):542–554.10.1016/j.chieco.2011.07.002Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2013-03-27

©2012 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin Boston

Downloaded on 30.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/jgd-2012-0009/html?lang=en
Scroll to top button