Abstract
The COVID-19 pandemic has disrupted established urban patterns. The literature on the impact of the pandemic on the US housing market has shown a significant increase in the demand for suburban housing, resulting in a considerable increase in suburban prices compared to those in the city center (termed the “donut effect”). However, the German housing market did not experience such drastic changes. To examine price and rent adjustments during the pandemic, we analyze detailed housing data and find little evidence supporting the donut effect seen in the US. Apartment rents increase in suburban areas, while house prices do not change significantly. Examining the role of amenities, we find no explanation for price and rent differences between the central business district (CBD) and suburbs. The differences between the two markets may be attributed to cultural and structural distinctions. Our analysis, which includes data on population patterns and migration behavior, reveals that residents in Germany exhibit a slower-moving trend. Our findings remain robust across different settings and subsets of cities.
1 Introduction
The key prediction of the Alonso (1964), Mills (1967), Muth (1969) (AMM) model is the rent gradient, which establishes a negative relationship between house prices or rents and distance from the city center. Lower commuting costs, higher amenities, and other agglomeration benefits justify higher prices in city centers than in the suburbs (Brueckner 1987). However, following the outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic, commuting costs have fallen or been eliminated because of the possibility of working from home (WFH), and urban consumption amenities were largely inaccessible because of strict lockdown measures. This may have reduced the demand for housing in city centers and dense neighborhoods within cities. Furthermore, there is strong evidence that the pandemic has caused significant population movements away from these areas to suburbs and low-density neighborhoods. However, much of the existing literature exclusively studies the US housing market (see, for example, Gupta et al. 2022; Liu and Su 2021; Ramani and Bloom 2021; Duranton and Handbury 2023). In this paper, we study how the COVID-19 pandemic and urban amenities affected real estate markets within and across German cities. In addition to adding the German experience to the current literature, our contribution is emphasizing the role of amenities. In the US literature, the WFH channel is championed as a potential explanation for changes in the housing market during the pandemic. The discussion of amenities is less detailed, although it is considered as a potential mechanism. We focus on house prices and apartment rents comparing them before and after the pandemic to document changes in the housing market.
The literature is limited on how the pandemic may have affected people’s preferences for local amenities and its subsequent impact on housing demand. This paper aims to highlight the pandemic’s impact on housing demand through the revaluation of amenities between consumption and environmental amenities. Our empirical strategy follows these predictions of housing demand reallocations. To test these predictions, we utilize data on house prices and apartment rents from the German housing market and amenities data from OpenStreetMap (OSM).
We find that, from March 2020 to March 2021, the slopes of the gradients have changed by 0.005 and 0.010 for prices and rents, respectively. Although the positive changes in the slopes show a flattening of the gradients, especially in the case of rents, the magnitudes are smaller compared to the US indicating not the same clear and strong flattening of gradients in Germany. For comparison, Gupta et al. (2022) found the change in slope for price 0.013, and the slope change for rents 0.032, from December 2019 to December 2020, for the US. In other words, while the US witnessed a decrease in price and rent gradients by 12.62 % and 100.00 %, respectively, a different picture emerged in Germany where the decreases were 9.38 % and 22.40 %. Thus, it is not evident that the pandemic has caused the same strong flattening of gradients in Germany as observed in the US. There appear to be only minor adjustments to the slopes of the gradients.
Overall, our results show little evidence of the flattening of the bid-rent curve in the German housing market. This result is robust to spatial subdivision into large, medium, or small cities. Amenities, our main mechanism, do not explain the (partial) donut effect. Based on our data, we do not observe a significant shift in the importance of consumption amenities towards environmental amenities, especially at the monthly level. We also find that residents in Germany did not move more than before the pandemic. We did not observe population movements within and between cities during the pandemic. Overall, according to our results, the German housing market has not been as disrupted by the COVID-19 pandemic as in the US. The differences may be attributed to institutional and cultural differences. The German housing market has proven to be fairly stable and resistant to disruption, as detailed in the Section 5.3.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provides a summary of the literature on the impact of the pandemic on housing markets and highlights key findings. Section 3 presents our empirical strategy, and Section 4 discusses the data sources. Section 5 presents our main findings. Section 6 concludes the paper.
2 Literature Review
Our work expands on the increasing volume of research exploring the intersection of the COVID-19 pandemic, remote work practices, amenities, and real estate markets. Several studies demonstrate that the pandemic has induced a redistribution of housing demand, population, and economic activities within cities, shifting from city centers and densely populated areas to suburban and less dense regions (Gupta et al. 2022; Liu and Su 2021; Ramani and Bloom 2021). Duranton and Handbury (2023) complement these studies by providing a comprehensive review of the effects of the pandemic and the rise of work from home (WFH) in cities, employing a version of the monocentric city model. The authors highlight the “commuting dividend”, i.e. the reduction in commuting cost due to increased time of WFH, and “home office tax”, the reduced consumption value of living space because a fraction of the home has to be attributed to office space as effects of WFH, noting short-term downtown housing price drops, subsequent rebounds, and continued suburban price rises. They connect the pandemic and WFH trends to changes in housing prices and commuting patterns and discuss potential challenges for maintaining vibrant downtown economies due to the loss of daytime workers and the potential impact on agglomeration benefits.
These studies collectively show how the pandemic flattened the bid rent curve in US metropolitan areas, causing house prices and rents in city centers to decrease while increasing in the suburbs. This led to a population shift from central urban areas to suburban locales. These changes in housing demand and population are most noticeable in metropolitan regions characterized by a high proportion of remote workers, strict lockdown measures, and inelastic housing supply (Gupta et al. 2022). The decrease in demand in densely populated and central urban neighborhoods is attributed to the diminished need for proximity to jobs that can be done remotely and the reduction in the appeal of urban amenities (Liu and Su 2021; Ramani and Bloom 2021).
This urban-to-suburban shift, dubbed the “donut effect” by Ramani and Bloom (2021), is not observed in smaller cities or movements across cities. The intercity relocations from larger, denser cities to smaller or less populated ones are less substantial, attributed in part to the emergence of hybrid work patterns in the post-pandemic period (Liu and Su 2021; Ramani and Bloom 2021).
The literature strongly supports a positive relationship between population density and the potential for WFH and the movement of workers with high WFH potential away from the CBD during the pandemic in the US (Althoff et al. 2022). Therefore, the question is how significant is WFH in the German context. Overall, the COVID-19 pandemic had a greater impact on the labor markets of major German cities compared to other regions, which experienced a faster recovery (Hamann et al. 2023). Thus, similar to the US, the effects seem to be present in large cities in Germany. Furthermore, Alipour, Falck, and Schüller (2023) shows that about 56 % of jobs in Germany can be performed (at least partially) from home, although there is great heterogeneity across occupational groups. The increase in WFH has also led to a shift in consumption patterns away from the CBDs to the suburbs, where people now also work from (Alipour et al. 2022). However, WFH is a much less valued job attribute than other job benefits. German workers report that they are willing to give up about 5 % of their income for the opportunity to work from home two days a week. The effects for other job benefits, such as additional paid days off, are two to three times greater (Nagler, Rincke, and Winkler 2022).
The other channel discussed for explaining the changes in real estate markets during the pandemic, albeit to a lesser extent, is the change in the valuation of (urban) amenities. The literature generally documents a positive impact of amenities on rents and prices (see, for example, Cho and Bowker 2006; Conway et al. 2010; Kolbe and Wüstemann 2015; Schäfer and Hirsch 2017). This applies to both environmental amenities, such as green spaces and water bodies, and consumption amenities, like fancy restaurants, cafes, and tourist attractions. However, these studies also show that the effect of amenities on house prices is typically smaller than the effect of structural variables such as the unit’s size or the building’s age. The key question for our study is whether the valuation of amenities changed with the pandemic. However, the literature is rather limited on this specific question. van Vuuren (2023) finds that house prices in amenity-rich areas decreased during the pandemic (compared to less amenity-rich areas) and that there is a reduction in willingness to pay for such amenities. Cheung and Fernandez (2021) examines the impact of amenities on house prices in Auckland (New Zealand) and finds that the premium paid for the enjoyment of amenities is reduced or even negative after the pandemic. They attribute this finding to changes in perceptions of open space, which may signal some risk following the experience of COVID-19. Another study by Batalha et al. (2022) shows that prices and rents in Lisbon and Porto, Portugal, decrease in tourist areas. However, tourist attractions may be a special type of amenity, as they are also typically associated with business activities. Overall, the evidence so far, however limited, points to a negative change in amenities due to the pandemic.
To the best of our knowledge, no study explicitly addresses the potential changes in the valuation of amenities during the pandemic in Germany. Therefore, this study emphasizes this second channel to explain changes in the housing market during the pandemic. An open question with respect to both WFH and amenities is whether developments during the pandemic caused population movements that led to structural changes in the German housing market. We investigate this question by analyzing post-pandemic population levels using county-level migration statistics.
3 Empirical Strategy
Theoretical considerations suggest that changes in commuting costs, central location attractiveness, and suburban amenities value lead to a reallocation of housing demand (Section A.1). There is a high concentration of consumption amenities near the CBD, while suburbs offer abundant environmental amenities. Due to the rapid spread of the COVID-19 virus in (high-density) areas during the pandemic, strict lockdown policies were enforced, limiting access to consumption amenities.[1] Consequently, people may have started valuing consumption amenities less since they are inaccessible and placing more importance on suburban amenities, causing high demand for suburban housing. This study aims to empirically examine if this holds true for the German housing market.
We test these predictions by analyzing changes in price and rent gradients following the pandemic. In line with the “flattening the curve” literature for the US, we would expect house prices and rents to fall in central locations and rise in suburbs during the pandemic in Germany, at least in big cities. To do so, we estimate the slope of the price and rent gradients for each month from 2017 to 2021.
To identify the impact of the pandemic on property prices in the CBD versus suburbs, like Gupta et al. (2022), we specify the following regression equation:
where log p ilt is the logarithm of average hedonic price or rent (described in Section 4.1) in zip code i located within labor market region (LMR) l, at time (i.e. month-year) t. log dist i is the logarithm of the (Euclidean) distance between the centroid of the zip code i and its CBD.[2] We control for zip code level cross-sectional characteristics x i .[3] Finally, time (α t ) and LMR fixed effects (α l ) are included to capture time trends and unobserved regional characteristics. A comparable regression analysis is conducted for central and suburban locations to ascertain group-specific patterns.
δ t , the coefficient of the interaction term between time t and distance, estimates the slope of the gradient for each month. We anticipate the estimates for this coefficient to be negative, as the AMM model predicts, and the magnitude to decrease in absolute terms during the pandemic, indicating a flattening of the gradient. The cutoff period for the pandemic is March 2020, corresponding to the time when the first lockdown was imposed in Germany.
To investigate the role of amenities, our main explanation channel for the donut effect, we specify the following regression equation.
where, in addition to the components of the previous equation, AI i represents an index of consumption or environmental amenities, all other elements remain the same as before. The coefficient of interest is δ t , the interaction between time and amenity indices. This interaction captures the effect of changes in the valuation of consumption or environmental amenities on house prices and rents following the pandemic. We expect the coefficient to be negative for consumption amenities and positive for environmental amenities, as predicted by theory (Section A.1.2).
4 Data
We use real estate data from RWI-GEO-RED of the FDZ Ruhr at RWI (RWI and ImmobilienScout24 (2022b) and RWI and ImmobilienScout24 (2022a)), and amenity data from OpenStreetMap (OSM).
4.1 Rents and House Prices
We construct house price and rental indices using a comprehensive and detailed dataset on housing RWI-GEO-RED (RWI and ImmobilienScout24 2022a, b). The dataset includes a wide range of property characteristics, enabling us to calculate hedonic indices.
To create a quality-adjusted index, we employ panel hedonic regression as follows:
where h, i, j, and t index properties, zip codes, municipalities, and times (i.e. month-year), respectively. The variable p denotes rent or price in euros per m2,
4.2 Zip Codes, Labor Market Regions (LMRs), and Central Business Districts (CBDs)
Our zip code data come from the Postleitzahlen Deutschland and covers all zip codes in Germany. The data contains information on zip code boundaries and associated towns and cities.
Kosfeld and Werner (2012) define 141 labor market regions (LMRs) in Germany, based on commuting flows. The delineation of these regions is based on combining one or more administrative regions at the county level to create self-contained labor markets. The boundaries of local labor markets are defined so that commuting flows within labor market regions are relatively large compared to commuting between regions, with an upper limit of 45–60 min for commuting time.
We use these LMRs to define the CBDs as the geographical center of each LMR, weighted by the number of inhabitants at the 1 × 1 km grid-cell level.[5] The information on the number of inhabitants comes from RWI and Microm (2022). Figure 1 shows the constructed CBD locations and the respective distance between the CBD and the center of each zip code.

CBD locations and distance to the CBD. Notes: The distance is calculated as the euclidean distance between the geographical center of the zip code and the CBD (dots) based on the LMR definition.
For a categorical classification of CBD and suburb, we rely on a data-driven definition of groups by using percentiles of the distance to the CBD. Locations within the 10th percentile are considered to belong to the CBD area (P 10 % ≈ 6.1 km). We classify locations above this threshold but below the median distance as suburban areas. For a more detailed analysis, we split the suburban areas into two rings: ring 1 with distances up P 30 % ≈ 12.4 km; ring 2 with distances up P 50 % ≈ 18.3 km. Zip codes with larger distances to the CBD lay outside the core area and are not further considered in this classification.
4.3 Amenities
We distinguish between two types of amenities – consumption amenities and environmental amenities. To model the presence of amenities in urban areas accurately, we rely on OpenStreetMap (OSM) data, which we extract for the period 2017 to 2021.[6] Consumption amenities combine places to eat, places for education, and places for entertainment. We categorize green spaces and water bodies as environmental amenities.[7]
The consumption amenities data are collected as point data. It is possible that we list multiple buildings belonging to an amenity. For example, even though a city may have only one university, its buildings may be scattered throughout the city, resulting in multiple data points in our sample. The environmental amenities data are collected as polygon data.
Figure 2 shows the distribution of consumption amenities (left panel) and environmental amenities (right panel) relative to the distance to the CBD for all zip codes. We report consumption amenities based on frequency, as these are represented by points in space. Environmental amenities are reported in terms of the area covered relative to the size of the zip code, as these are represented as polygons. The figure shows that consumption amenities have a higher frequency closer to the CBD, as indicated by the decreasing slope of the trend line. The pattern is less clear for environmental amenities. Here, the slope of the trend line is close to zero, indicating evenly distributed amenities. However, the stylized facts (Section A.2) show locations further away from the CBD benefit, on average, from larger environmental areas. The trade-off between consumption and environmental amenities may influence households’ decisions on where to live. Those prioritizing consumption amenities may reside closer to the CBD, while those who value environmental amenities may prefer suburban locations.

The gradient of amenities (raw values) as a function of the distance to the CBD. Notes: Both panels illustrate the relationship between amenities and their distance to the CBD, with data points coded green representing zip code values and darker points representing averages within a 2 km distance bins. (a) Consumption amenities. (b) Environmental amenities.
We transform the raw data into a zip code dataset to make consumption and environmental amenities usable in the analysis. We use the frequency of consumption amenities and the area covered by environmental amenities, which are normalized into an index using z-score normalization.[8] Following this strategy has the advantage that the resulting indices have a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one, making them comparable despite having different units.[9]
5 Results
5.1 Development of Bid-Rent Curves
While the pandemic appears to be affecting the trend of apartment rents in Germany, average house prices have remained unaffected, as shown in Figure 3. In Germany, average rents started decreasing at the beginning of 2020, coinciding with the onset of the pandemic. Rents recovered to the pre-pandemic (late 2019) levels in late 2020. However, the trend repeats starting in January 2021, with rents falling throughout 2021, albeit at a lower rate, paralleling the second wave of the pandemic. Since increasing rents by landlords is highly unlikely due to rental controls in Germany, the downturn in rents may have been triggered by the decline in demand, especially in major German cities and high-density areas.

Trends of house prices and rents relative to March 2020. Notes: Note that the data is smoothed using a 3-month moving average.
With respect to house prices, the figure shows a steady increasing pattern which is not interrupted by the pandemic. This may be due to several factors. House prices are forward-looking, and home buyers likely anticipate a recovery from the pandemic by 2021 therefore, showing no (immediate) response to COVID-19. In addition, low interest rates may have supported demand for houses, and housing supply constraints on new construction may have limited the availability of homes for purchase.
Overall, the trends suggest that while the pandemic directly impacted apartment rents, house prices were more resilient, likely due to a combination of demand, supply, and financial factors.
A key finding in the literature is that suburban housing prices and rents increased while those in the CBD locations decreased during the pandemic in the US (see, for example, Gupta et al. (2022)). However, according to our results, this pattern is not strongly observed in the German housing market. Figure 4 shows the relationship between hedonic prices (left panel) and hedonic rents (right panel) and the distance to the CBD for March 2020 and March 2021. Both price and rent gradients have a negative slope, consistent with the key prediction of the AMM model that prices or rents decrease with the distance to the CBD.

The price and rent gradients for March 2020 and 2021. Notes: The figure illustrates the relationship between the distance to the CBD, house prices, and apartment rents, comparing the pre-pandemic (March 2020) and pandemic (March 2021) periods. As expected, in both periods, the gradients are negatively sloping, indicating that prices and rents decrease as the distance from the CBD increases. Lighter points represent zip code values, whereas darker points represent averages within a 2 km distance bins. (a) Prices, (b) Rents.
However, we do not observe any effects of the pandemic leveling the bid-rent curves, at least not in terms of prices. The price curves appear equally parallel in March 2020 and March 2021 (Figure 4 left panel). The slope is slightly flatter for the rent gradient in March 2021 than in March 2020, although the difference is marginal. We also provide additional evidence that strengthens this finding in the Appendix by plotting the change in house prices and rents against the distance to the CBD and comparing the pandemic levels with pre-pandemic values (see Figures A.3 and A.4). If the US pattern carries over to the German setting, we expect suburban areas to experience positive growth in both prices and rents as suburban housing or rental demand increases due to the pandemic. However, there is no clear evidence that this is the case for the German housing market.
Figure 5 displays the estimates of the slopes of the gradients specified in Equation (1) for each month. The slope of the price gradient shows greater fluctuations in the point estimates but maintains a similar trend as the pre-pandemic time. In contrast, the slope of the rent gradient exhibits a smoother gradual increase over time, starting in late 2019, suggesting that the rent gradient has become flatter during the pandemic.

Estimates for the price and rent gradients. Notes: This figure shows the estimated slopes of the price and rent gradients, which were obtained from the regression in Equation (1). log p and log r are regressed on log dist × time, with time and LMR fixed effects. The zip code controls include the logarithm of purchasing power, the share of males aged 18–45, and the share of individuals with a German background. (a) Prices, (b) Rents.
Quantitatively, our estimation results show that the estimated slopes of the gradients are:
That means, from March 2020 to March 2021, the slopes of the gradients have changed by:
Overall, the changes in slope estimates during the pandemic appear small: the decreases in the gradients’ slopes are 9.38 % and 22.40 % for house prices and rents, respectively. This might suggest that the pandemic has led to a flattening of gradients in Germany, but not as clearly and strongly as observed in the US.
Another approach, as used by Ramani and Bloom (2021), for identifying the donut effect involves dividing the data into CBD and suburban regions and examining the growth of house prices and rents. Figure 6 shows the evolution of prices for the CBD (in red) and the two suburban rings (in green/blue) estimated for the full sample. The plot shows that the evolution of rents breaks with the onset of the pandemic (right panel Figure 6). While rents increased before March 2020, they stagnated shortly after the start of the pandemic. Rents increased again in the summer of 2020 but then decreased for all three groups. At the beginning of 2021, rents in CBDs appear to fall more sharply than in locations further away from the city center. This suggests a delayed donut effect, at least partially and less strongly than in the US.

The donut effect for the full sample. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Prices, (b) Rents.
The evolution for prices is even less pronounced (left panel Figure 6). Here, all three groups move in the same direction and show a continuous increase over time.
The donut effect is most prominent in big cities (Ramani and Bloom 2021). We test this prediction by re-estimating the model only for the 15 largest German cities with approximately 500,000 residents or more. Figure 7 shows that all lines are more volatile for both rents (right panel) and prices (left panel) across all areas. The partial donut effect for rents from the full sample also disappears. Thus, we cannot confirm that the donut effect is strongest in the largest cities in Germany. The indicated donut effect in the full sample comes from medium-sized cities with a population of at least 100,000 but less than 500,000, as shown in Figure A.5 in the Appendix. We also do the same exercise for small cities (below 100,000 in population) and find no evidence of the donut effect (see Figure A.6 in the Appendix).

Donut effect for the 15 largest cities. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Prices, (b) Rents.
5.2 The Role of Amenities
The literature identifies WFH and amenities as potential channels to explain the housing market results. Due to data limitations and since WFH seems to be weakly valued in Germany (see, for example, Nagler, Rincke, and Winkler (2022)), we focus on the second channel – the change in the valuation of (urban) amenities.
To assess the valuation of amenities, particularly the potential change during the pandemic, we estimate Equation (2), which includes a continuous time measure with effects relative to March 2020. Figure 8 shows the plotted interaction effects for each month for prices and Figure 9 shows the effects for rents without spatially restricting the sample. Regardless of the type of dwelling and the amenity considered, there seems to be a slight decreasing trend in the value of amenities after the pandemic, but almost all interactions are insignificant. There is little to no evidence that the value of amenities changed during the pandemic. We have also tested the same analysis for CBD and suburbs in the Appendix, with the same result (Figures A.8–13).

Amenities’ values over time with respect to prices – full sample. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Consumption amenities, (b) Environmental amenities.

Amenities’ values over time with respect to rents – full sample. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Consumption amenities, (b) Environmental amenities.
Overall, the results suggest that bid-rent curves in Germany have not flattened, except for rents, where there is only slight evidence. This conclusion is reasonable because WFH is not seen as a compelling job attribute in Germany, the value of amenities remains unchanged, and there is little population movement during the pandemic (Figure A.7).
5.3 Discussion on Differences Between the US and Germany
The disparities in the pandemic’s donut effects on the US and German housing markets can be attributed to institutional and cultural differences between the two markets.
Homeownership Culture and Rental Market Dominance. The United States and Germany exhibit contrasting housing market dynamics. The US is characterized by a strong homeownership culture, whereas Germany is dominated by the rental market. In the United States, the rate of homeownership has remained relatively stable at around 63–65 % over several decades. This reflects both a cultural preference for home ownership and the presence of supportive policies that have proven resilient in the face of global crises (see Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (2024)). Surveys conducted by the National Association of Realtors (NAR),[11] have consistently demonstrated that the primary motivation for purchasing a home is the desire to own property. In 2019 and 2020, 29 % of all buyers identified this as their main reason (National Association of Realtors (NAR) 2019, 2020).[12] The United States’ tax policies, such as the Home Mortgage Interest Deduction (allowing tax deductions on the first $750,000 of home mortgage interest), provide an incentive for home ownership by reducing the tax burden associated with mortgages, thus making home buying more attractive and financially feasible for many (see Internal Revenue Service (IRS) (2023)). Conversely, in Germany, only 41.8 % of households owned their homes in 2022, a figure that serves to illustrate the extent to which rental culture has become ingrained in German society (see Federal Statistical Office (2024)). Despite the financial stability, many Germans continue to prefer renting. The Bundesbank Panel Survey of Households in 2022 revealed that only 37 % of German households would choose to buy a home even if no down payment were required (see Deutsche Bundesbank (2023)). Germany’s rigorous tax policies on home sales, which discourage hasty resales, and robust rental regulations contribute to a diminished sense of urgency to purchase, further dampened by a dearth of flexibility in relocating. This structure fosters stability but stands in stark contrast to the US market, where both culture and policy support a highly mobile, ownership-oriented housing market, leading to greater flexibility and contributing to differences in the estimated effects.
Government intervention and market stabilizers The German and American governments have adopted markedly different approaches to housing market stabilization, reflecting distinct priorities and regulatory philosophies. In Germany, government institutions play an active role in maintaining housing affordability and stability through the implementation of substantial rental regulations, the provision of direct housing benefits, and investments in social housing, which is also known as “sozialer Wohnungsbau”. The “Wohngeld” (housing benefits) program, which was initiated in 1965, provides financial assistance to both renters and owner-occupants, thereby ensuring that housing costs remain within the financial capabilities of lower-income households. In 2020, approximately 1.5 % of German households benefited from this support, as documented by the Federal Ministry for Housing, Urban Development and Building (BMWSB) (2023a) and Federal Ministry of Justice (FMJ) (2008). Furthermore, Germany has pledged approximately one billion euros annually from 2020 to 2024 to subsidize social housing construction, thereby facilitating access to affordable housing for low-income households through low-interest credit programs (see Federal Ministry for Housing, Urban Development and Building (BMWSB) (2023b)). The Tenancy Law Amendment Act (TLAA) of 2013 and the Rent Freeze (Mietpreisbremse) of 2015, two legislative tools, serve to further cap rent increases in high-demand areas. This has the effect of preventing significant price surges and promoting long-term housing stability.[13] In contrast, the United States relies more on market-driven forces to dictate housing costs, with limited government intervention primarily in the form of targeted support, such as the Housing Choice Voucher Program (Section 8), which aids low-income households in renting private market properties (see NYC Housing Authority (2024)). This market-based approach offers greater price flexibility, enabling more rapid adjustments in response to shifts in demand, as evidenced by the rising prices of housing in suburban areas in response to increased demand. Although this enables dynamic pricing and relocation, it frequently lacks the structural stabilisers present in Germany’s housing market, resulting in greater volatility in housing costs.
Housing supply constrains and zoning differences The discrepancy in urban and suburban development between Germany and the United States can also be attributed to the interplay of housing supply constraints and zoning regulations. In Germany, the combination of restrictive policies and a constrained housing supply has led to a notable limitation in suburban expansion. This is evidenced by the decline in construction permits issued in recent years, which has further constrained the availability of housing.[14] The limited availability of housing, coupled with rent controls, has resulted in a relatively stable demand for housing across urban and suburban areas. This has led to an increase in the length of time residents are willing to remain in their current place of residence. The German zoning policies that prioritize a mixed-use approach permit residential areas to exist in close proximity to commercial and business spaces, thereby creating neighborhoods where housing is situated in close proximity to essential services and amenities (see Hirt (2007)). In contrast, the United States employs a single-use zoning approach, whereby extensive areas are designated for exclusive use as residential, commercial, or business zones. This approach frequently restricts the construction of multi-unit buildings in single-family home neighborhoods, resulting in the formation of homogeneous residential zones and, in numerous instances, a lifestyle that is more reliant on automobiles (see Plenk (2022)). Consequently, while Germany’s zoning regulations facilitate the creation of integrated, accessible communities, the United States’ model encourages the development of distinct, sprawling residential and commercial zones. This has significant implications for housing supply flexibility and the resulting differences in urban structure and mobility, particularly with regard to commuting patterns. While the average German lives closer to their place of work, a larger proportion of Americans are required to commute longer distances, potentially providing an incentive for relocation during the pandemic and the adoption of remote working practices.[15] Furthermore, there is no dramatic change in population levels in either the CBD or the suburbs in Germany. We analyzed the population information offered by RWI and Microm (2023), and observed minimal population changes compared to the pre-pandemic levels in 2019. We also used information on migration across city boundaries provided by Federal Statistical Office (2023). The data shows a very stable pattern of movement into or out of German cities for the years 2017–2021. While this data considers movement across cities rather than within cities, which is our focus here, it provides suggestive evidence that residents in Germany do not tend to move frequently and probably less so in uncertain times.
The disparate structures of the U.S. and German housing markets provide a rationale for the divergent donut effect dynamics. In the United States, a robust homeownership culture, market-driven pricing, and single-use zoning contribute to a flexible housing market with greater suburban expansion and easier relocation. This flexibility has resulted in a notable increase in suburban property prices. Conversely, Germany’s rental-oriented culture, protective housing policies, and mixed-use zoning contribute to the stabilization of demand across urban and suburban areas, thereby limiting the potential for significant suburban price increases. Due to the presence of restrictive housing supply constraints, lower relocation rates, and stable population distributions, the German market demonstrates a diminished donut effect, with housing demand remaining relatively consistent across regions.
6 Conclusions
The COVID-19 pandemic has weakened a fundamental tenet of urban economics: the inverse relationship between proximity to the city center and housing prices. However, this conclusion appears to apply mostly to the US housing market and less so to the German housing market, as indicated by the findings of this study.
We used comprehensive zip code-level data on housing prices and rents to examine temporal changes, comparing pre- and post-pandemic periods. We found no strong evidence for the flattening of the bid-rent curve in the case of house prices where the development between CBD and suburban areas remained unchanged during the pandemic. However, we discovered that during the pandemic, rents in suburbs and low-density zip codes have slightly increased compared to those in the CBD and high-density zip codes.
We analyzed urban amenities to explain the impact of the pandemic on rents, but we did not find any significant effect. Our amenity data, constructed from OSM, shows that the valuation of consumption and environmental amenities remains relatively stable. All findings are consistent across various city center definitions and regional subsets, such as big cities versus small cities.
This leads us to conclude that institutional and structural differences between Germany and the US may contribute to the stability of the German housing market. The German housing market is characterized by extensive governmental support, a large renter population, tax legislation restricting speculative behavior, and low interest rates. Our analysis of population and migration data suggests that residents in Germany are less responsive to location changes related to the pandemic.
Therefore, while the COVID-19 pandemic has undeniably posed challenges globally, its impact on the German housing market, as explored in this study, seems to be less disruptive compared to other countries such as the US. Further research may be beneficial to fully understand the long-term implications of the pandemic on real estate markets.
Acknowledgments
We want to thank Tobias Seidel and Thomas Bauer for their valuable comments and suggestions, and Lukas Hörnig for his early contributions to this paper. We also thank participants at RWI and MSM internal seminars, and the RGS doctoral conference, for insightful remarks.
-
Author contributions: The authors have accepted responsibility for the entire content of this manuscript and approved its submission. Eyayaw Beze – Data preparation, analysis and text Patrick Thiel – Data preparation, analysis and text.
-
Conflict of interest: The authors state no conflict of interest.
-
Research funding: None declared.
-
Data availability: The raw data can be obtained on request from the corresponding author.
A.1 Theoretical Considerations
The section offers a theoretical framework for understanding the relationship between real estate prices and the distance to the city center, as well as the role of amenities in such a setting.
Following Duranton and Handbury (2023), we consider a city that produces its consumption good in its downtown, often called the central business district (CBD), where all jobs are concentrated. Residents derive utility from the consumption good, denoted q, sold at a fixed price of one, and housing, denoted h measured in square meters of floorspace. Every location in the city is indexed by d, representing the distance to the CBD. Housing is supplied competitively across the city from the CBD (where d = 0) to the urban fringe (where
Residents’ preferences are represented by a utility function u (h, q, A(d)), where A represents local amenities, which is a function of d. We assume that utility is increasing in all three arguments and is strictly quasi-concave.
A resident living at a distance d from the CBD incurs a commuting cost of td τ , where τ < 1. This implies that commuting costs increase disproportionately with distance.[16] Let r(d) denote the rental price of floorspace per unit of housing at a distance d from the CBD. The resident’s budget constraint can be expressed as w − td τ = r(d)h + q, where w represents income.[17]
We assume a Cobb-Douglas form for the utility function:
where α reflects the importance of housing in utility, with α ∈ (0, 1).
Solving the utility maximization problem subject to the budget constraint yields the demand functions for housing and the consumption good:
Note that these solutions do not include the effect of amenities A directly. In this simplified model, amenities affect utility but do not directly affect the budget constraint. Thus, they do not appear in the optimal choice of consuming h and q. However, they affect the location choice of the resident and thus the price of housing r(d), which indirectly affects housing and consumption choices.
A.1.1 Spatial Equilibrium
Assuming that all residents in the city are homogeneous in incomes and preferences and are freely mobile within the city, the concept of “spatial equilibrium” states that they should attain the same level of utility, represented by
That means, residents that live in the CBD d = 0 and in the suburb
The spatial equilibrium condition implies that residents have no utility gains by moving from one location to another within the city. Therefore, the total derivative of utility with respect to distance must be zero.
We obtain the equilibrium price difference between the CBD and the suburb by inserting the respective distances and using the optimal choice values in Equation A.2.
Taking the logarithm yields the equilibrium percentage difference between the CBD and the suburb prices:
This equation shows that the relative commute cost and amenity levels determine the price difference. Higher amenities or lower commuting costs for the suburb (due to lower t) increase the price in the suburb relative to the CBD, and the price difference decreases, all else being equal.
A.1.2 Introducing Amenity Shock
The COVID-19 pandemic has caused a WFH shock and a potential revaluation of amenities. Since the beginning of the pandemic, access to consumption amenities has been largely restricted due to strict lockdown and social distancing measures. Moreover, the virus has been spreading rapidly, resulting in higher infection and death rates in high-density central locations within cities. It is crucial to capture these local shocks to amenities to understand the effects of the pandemic on housing demand.
We build upon the above part by providing more specific information about amenities to introduce an amenity shock. In the pre-pandemic time, amenity enters the utility of a representative resident as U (h, q, A(d)) = h a ⋅ q 1−α ⋅ (κA c + ɛA e ) where A c and A e denote consumption and environmental amenities. The parameters κ and ɛ are weights that represent the relative importance placed by the resident on each type of amenity, respectively. During the pandemic, the relative importance of consumption and environmental amenities may change due to factors such as the closure of establishments in the CBD or the increased preference for open spaces in the suburb. We consider this shift by modifying the utility function during the pandemic to U′, which now has κ′A C + ɛ′A E in the amenity component, where κ′ < κ represents the decreased weight of consumption amenities in the CBD due to closures and restrictions, and ɛ′ > ɛ represents the increased weight of environmental amenities in the suburb due to greater emphasis on open space and nature during lockdowns or WFH periods. The utility maximization problem now involves comparisons between altered utilities of living in or close to the CBD and further away. Residents reevaluate their preferences based on these changes in amenities and other considerations such as moving and commuting costs. As a result, we may observe a shift in housing demand from the CBD towards the suburb during the pandemic period.
Furthermore, it is important to highlight that consumption amenities, such as access to fancy restaurants, shops, and entertainment venues, are highly concentrated in the CBD, and their availability is limited in the suburbs. In contrast, environmental amenities, such as open space, clean air, and quieter neighborhoods, are scarce in the CBD but more abundant in the suburbs. The amenity function, as defined below, captures this heterogeneity:
where a c and a e represent the maximum (minimum) consumption (environmental) amenity levels in the city at the CBD, and the parameters b and ϕ determine how fast each amenity type changes with distance from the CBD.
For simplicity, suppose
Equation A.7 indicates that the price difference is a function of the weights residents give to amenities. Specifically, the price difference is smaller when residents place greater importance on environmental amenities. In addition, as residents move farther from the CBD, the availability of consumption amenities decreases while the availability of environmental amenities increases.
Taking derivatives of the left-hand side of the equation with respect to κ and ɛ provides the change in the price differential as a function of a change in the weights assigned to consumption and environmental amenities, respectively.
Specifically, we have:
These equations describe how a small change in the relative importance of consumption or environmental amenities affects the log price/rent differential between the CBD and the suburb. If κ′ < κ (i.e. the relative importance of consumption amenities decreases), then
This simple model demonstrates how commuting costs and amenities determine residential choices and the spatial distribution of housing prices in an equilibrium setting. It predicts that housing demand will shift from the CBD to the suburbs due to the increased value of suburban amenities, decreased value of consumption amenities, and the rise of remote work arrangements during the pandemic. This shift is expected to cause a decline in CBD prices and an increase in suburban prices. Before the pandemic, when remote work was not prevalent, commuting costs were high, and there was a strong preference for consumption amenities, CBD house prices and rents were higher. However, during the pandemic, with widespread remote work and a greater preference for suburban amenities, the price and rent differences between CBD and suburbs become smaller, resulting in declining CBD prices and rents and increasing suburban prices and rents.[18]
A.2 Distribution of Amenities
Stylized Fact 1: Consumption amenities are more prevalent in the CBD, while environmental amenities cover larger areas in the suburbs. Table A.1 shows the average number of consumption amenities and the area covered by environmental amenities, based on our definition of CBD and suburbs. The number of consumption amenities decreases with distance to the CBD. On average, the CBD (within a distance of 6.1 km from the center location) has approximately 22 consumption amenities (such as restaurants, schools, etc.). In the suburban ring 1 (6.1–12.4 km), there are only about 16 such facilities, and in the suburban ring 2 (12.4–18.3 km), there are about 13 facilities. For environmental amenities, on average, the area covered by these amenities increases from the CBD to the suburbs, ranging from 0.07 to 0.14 square kilometers.
Descriptive statistics on amenities.
Consumption amenities | Environmental amenities | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Ring | N | SD | Covered area (km2) | SD |
CBD | 21.86 | 31.78 | 0.07 | 0.49 |
Suburb ring 1 | 15.76 | 20.46 | 0.09 | 0.32 |
Suburb ring 2 | 12.63 | 16.55 | 0.14 | 0.81 |
Outside | 10.21 | 14.17 | 0.19 | 0.84 |
-
The table shows the average number of consumption amenities and the average area covered by environmental amenities for the CBD and the suburban locations. Source: Authors’ table.
Overall, this indicates that urban dwellers can avail themselves of consumption facilities more frequently, but they must also share a narrower range of environmental resources with their neighbors. Conversely, suburban residents have access to larger expanses of greenery and aquatic features, although they may have to undertake longer journeys to access consumption amenities.
Stylized Fact 2: While consumption amenities are negatively associated with the distance to the CBD, environmental amenities are positively associated.
Equation A.6 demonstrates that the consumption amenities parameter b exhibits a negative sign while the environmental amenities parameter ϕ exhibits a positive one. Empirical evidence supporting this theoretical relationship can be ascertained through regression of the constructed amenity indices against the distance from the CBD.
The results in Table A.2 indicate a significant negative effect of distance to the CBD on consumption amenities. The coefficient for environmental amenities (measured as the area covered) is significant and positive, but it is not significant for the index.
Estimates for the parameters b and ϕ.
Type | Consumption amenities | Environmental amenities | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
ln count | Index | ln area km2 | Index | |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
Constant | 4.323*** | 0.9777*** | −6.538*** | 0.0169 |
(0.0117) | (0.0508) | (0.0320) | (0.0485) | |
ln dist | −0.2468*** | −0.3508*** | 0.1669*** | −0.0063 |
(0.0050) | (0.0166) | (0.0132) | (0.0183) | |
Observations | 65,830 | 8,478 | 65,830 | 3,800 |
R2 | 0.03564 | 0.08925 | 0.00231 | 3.13 × 10−5 |
-
The table shows the estimates for the parameters b and ϕ from Equation (A.6), which represent the relationship between amenities and the distance to the CBD. The estimation uses amenity data for 2019. The number of observations for the indices represents zip codes. In the raw data, the number of observations counts the amenity object.
Stylized Fact 3: The valuation of consumption and environmental amenities remains relatively constant in Germany during and after the pandemic.
Figure A.1 shows the relationship between hedonic prices (rents) and the amenity indices in the top (bottom) panels. The relationship between hedonic values and amenities appears almost identical for both prices and rents. While the price trend for environmental amenities is flat in 2020 and 2021, the slope of the 2021 line for consumption amenities is slightly steeper than in 2020 (compare panels (a) and (b)). This implies that the valuation of consumption amenities with regard to house prices has increased in 2021. This minor change may be attributed to the pandemic and the closure of amenities such as high-end restaurants and cafes due to lockdown and social distancing measures. The (partial) reopening of these establishments and improved pandemic coping strategies may have enhanced the appreciation of local amenities. In contrast, the assessment of both facilities in relation to rental rates shows minimal variation between the onset of the pandemic in March 2020 and March 2021.
A.3 Additional Figures and Tables

Correlation between prices/rents and amenities in March 2020 and 2021. (a) Prices: Consumption amenities, (b) Prices: Environmental amenities, (c) Rents: Consumption amenities, (d) Rents: Environmental amenities.

Density of distance to the CBD by CBD types. Notes: The figure illustrates the density of distances to the CBD by different types of CBDs. The CBDs are defined based on the geocentroid of the LMR (unweighted), weighted by the number of inhabitants, the number of residential buildings, and the number of households. The fourth type is based on the most populous municipality’s centroid in the county, similar to Ahlfeldt et al. (2020).

Changes in log prices/rents against distance to the CBD. Notes: The figure illustrates the relationship between the distance to the CBD and changes in log house prices and apartment rents from the pre-pandemic (March 2020) to the pandemic (March 2021) periods. The expected pattern is upward-sloping curves, indicating that prices and rents tend to increase as the distance from the CBD increases. However, this pattern cannot be observed here, as the curves appear to be almost horizontal. Lighter points represent zip code values, whereas darker points represent averages within a 2 km distance bins.

Changes in log prices/rents against the pre-pandemic levels. Notes: The figure illustrates the relationship between pre-pandemic levels and changes in log house prices and apartment rents from the pre-pandemic period (March 2020) to the pandemic period (March 2021). The expected trend is a downward slope, indicating that zip codes with high prices and rents before the pandemic would experience lower or negative changes. This pattern is evident in the graph, with fitted lines sloping downwards for both prices and rents. Lighter points represent zip code values, whereas darker points represent averages within a 2 km distance bins.

The donut effect for medium-sized cities. Notes: Medium-sized cities are classified as having a population between 100,000 and 500,000. The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Prices, b) Rents.e

The donut effect for small cities. Notes: Small cities have a population of 100,000 or less. The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Prices, (b) Rents.

Population levels across CBD and suburban areas. Notes: The figure shows the total population for the CBD and suburban locations from 2017 to 2021 (left panel) and the population change relative to 2019 (right panel). (a) Total population, (b) Population change.

Amenities’ values over time with respect to price – CBD locations. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Consumption amenities, (b) Environmental amenities.

Amenities’ values over time with respect to price – suburban ring 1. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic.

Amenities’ values over time with respect to price – suburban ring 2. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Consumption amenities, (b) Environmental amenities.

Amenities’ values over time with respect to rents – CBD locations. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Consumption amenities, (b) Environmental amenities.

Amenities’ values over time with respect to rents – suburban ring 1. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Consumption amenities, (b) Environmental amenities.

Amenities’ values over time with respect to rents – suburban ring 2. Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates March 2020, the start of the pandemic. (a) Consumption amenities, (b) Environmental amenities.
Slope estimates of the housing price and rent gradients.
log p | log r | |
---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | |
Jan2019 × log dist | −0.0682*** (0.0134) | −0.0418*** (0.0092) |
Feb2019 × log dist | −0.0600*** (0.0132) | −0.0449*** (0.0092) |
Mar2019 × log dist | −0.0659*** (0.0132) | −0.0462*** (0.0096) |
Apr2019 × log dist | −0.0605*** (0.0146) | −0.0481*** (0.0100) |
May2019 × log dist | −0.0586*** (0.0137) | −0.0479*** (0.0098) |
Jun2019 × log dist | −0.0683*** (0.0161) | −0.0466*** (0.0100) |
Jul2019 × log dist | −0.0564*** (0.0153) | −0.0447*** (0.0103) |
Aug2019 × log dist | −0.0634*** (0.0154) | −0.0438*** (0.0103) |
Sep2019 × log dist | −0.0617*** (0.0156) | −0.0447*** (0.0099) |
Oct2019 × log dist | −0.0711*** (0.0154) | −0.0416*** (0.0103) |
Nov2019 × log dist | −0.0678*** (0.0172) | −0.0437*** (0.0099) |
Dec2019 × log dist | −0.0626*** (0.0162) | −0.0438*** (0.0097) |
Jan2020 × log dist | −0.0467*** (0.0168) | −0.0452*** (0.0094) |
Feb2020 × log dist | −0.0539*** (0.0150) | −0.0446*** (0.0090) |
Mar2020 × log dist | −0.0518*** (0.0146) | −0.0443*** (0.0093) |
Apr2020 × log dist | −0.0570*** (0.0145) | −0.0439*** (0.0092) |
May2020 × log dist | −0.0570*** (0.0137) | −0.0431*** (0.0088) |
Jun2020 × log dist | −0.0652*** (0.0140) | −0.0421*** (0.0085) |
Jul2020 × log dist | −0.0589*** (0.0144) | −0.0418*** (0.0086) |
Aug2020 × log dist | −0.0562*** (0.0142) | −0.0412*** (0.0086) |
Sep2020 × log dist | −0.0625*** (0.0141) | −0.0384*** (0.0085) |
Oct2020 × log dist | −0.0582*** (0.0133) | −0.0404*** (0.0084) |
Nov2020 × log dist | −0.0626*** (0.0143) | −0.0388*** (0.0085) |
Dec2020 × log dist | −0.0623*** (0.0144) | −0.0396*** (0.0083) |
Jan2021 × log dist | −0.0481*** (0.0134) | −0.0398*** (0.0087) |
Feb2021 × log dist | −0.0530*** (0.0139) | −0.0364*** (0.0087) |
Mar2021 × log dist | −0.0469*** (0.0131) | −0.0344*** (0.0092) |
Apr2021 × log dist | −0.0569*** (0.0128) | −0.0349*** (0.0092) |
May2021 × log dist | −0.0537*** (0.0129) | −0.0366*** (0.0086) |
Jun2021 × log dist | −0.0535*** (0.0142) | −0.0339*** (0.0081) |
Jul2021 × log dist | −0.0482*** (0.0141) | −0.0341*** (0.0084) |
Aug2021 × log dist | −0.0367** (0.0141) | −0.0315*** (0.0080) |
Sep2021 × log dist | −0.0405*** (0.0139) | −0.0308*** (0.0085) |
Oct2021 × log dist | −0.0500*** (0.0145) | −0.0300*** (0.0085) |
Nov2021 × log dist | −0.0417*** (0.0140) | −0.0340*** (0.0093) |
Observations | 253,828 | 235,270 |
R2 | 0.76713 | 0.80604 |
Within R2 | 0.21043 | 0.32698 |
LMR fixed effects | ✓ | ✓ |
Time fixed effects | ✓ | ✓ |
-
We control for the share of males aged 18–45, the share of German background, and the logarithm of total purchasing power at the zip code level. The estimates for 2017 and 2018 are not shown to fit the table. The standard errors are clustered at the level of the LMR.
References
Ahlfeldt, G. M., F. Bald, D. Roth, and T. Seidel. 2020. Quality of Life in a Dynamic Spatial Model. CEP Discussion Papers dp1736, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE. https://www.cesifo.org/en/publikationen/2020/working-paper/quality-life-dynamic-spatial-model.10.2139/ssrn.3751857Search in Google Scholar
Alipour, J.-V., O. Falck, S. Krause, C. Krolage, and S. Wichert. 2022. “The Future of Work and Consumption in Cities after the Pandemic: Evidence from Germany.” SSRN Electronic Journal https://www.ssrn.com/abstract=4255438.10.2139/ssrn.4255438Search in Google Scholar
Alipour, J.-V., O. Falck, and S. Schüller. 2023. “Germany’s Capacity to Work from Home.” European Economic Review 151: 104354. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2022.104354. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0014292122002343 Search in Google Scholar
Alonso, W. 1964. Location and Land Use: toward a General Theory of Land Rent. Harvard University Press. https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.4159/harvard.9780674730854/html.10.4159/harvard.9780674730854Search in Google Scholar
Althoff, L., F. Eckert, S. Ganapati, and C. Walsh. 2022. “The Geography of Remote Work.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 93: 103770. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2022.103770. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0166046222000011 Search in Google Scholar
Batalha, M., D. Gonçalves, S. Peralta, and J. Pereira dos Santos. 2022. “The Virus that Devastated Tourism: The Impact of Covid-19 on the Housing Market.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 95: 103774. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2022.103774. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0166046222000059 Search in Google Scholar
Brueckner, J. K. 1987. “The Structure of Urban Equilibria: A Unified Treatment of the Muth-Mills Model.” In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, Vol. 2, 821–45. Elsevier. https://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S1574008087800068.10.1016/S1574-0080(87)80006-8Search in Google Scholar
Bureau, U. S. C. 2021. S0801: Commuting Characteristics by Sex. https://data.census.gov/table/ACSST1Y2021.S0801?q=S0801:+COMMUTING+CHARACTERISTICS+BY+SEX&hidePreview=true.Search in Google Scholar
Cheung, L., and M. A. Fernandez. 2021. “Changes in Amenity Values after COVID-19 Lockdowns in Auckland, New Zealand.” Economic Papers: A journal of applied economics and policy 40 (4): 331–50. https://doi.org/10.1111/1759-3441.12329. https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1111/1759-3441.12329.Search in Google Scholar
Cho, S. H., and J. M. Bowker. 2006. “Measuring the Contribution of Water and Green Space Amenities to Housing Values: An Application and Comparison of Spatially Weighted Hedonic Models.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 485–507.Search in Google Scholar
Conway, D., C. Q. Li, J. Wolch, C. Kahle, and M. Jerrett. 2010. “A Spatial Autocorrelation Approach for Examining the Effects of Urban Greenspace on Residential Property Values.” The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 41 (2): 150–69. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-008-9159-6.Search in Google Scholar
Deutsche Bundesbank. 2023. “Kaufen oder mieten? Wie Eigenkapitalanforderungen für private Haushalte die Entscheidungen bei der Eigenheimfinanzierung beeinflussen.” Research Brief (Vol. 60) https://www.bundesbank.de/de/publikationen/forschung/research-brief/2023-60-eigenheimfinanzierung-662714.Search in Google Scholar
Duranton, G., and J. Handbury. 2023. “Covid and Cities, Thus Far.” 29 6–52. https://doi.org/10.59576/epr.29.2.6-52. https://www.nber.org/papers/w31158.Search in Google Scholar
Federal Institute for Research on Building, Urban Affairs and Spatial Development (BBSR). 2024. “Mietpreisbremse und Kappungsgrenze: Wie die Regelungen in den Ländern umgesetzt werden.” https://www.bbsr.bund.de/BBSR/DE/forschung/fachbeitraege/wohnen-immobilien/mieten-preise/mietpreisbremse/01-start.html.Search in Google Scholar
Federal Ministry for Housing, Urban Development and Building (BMWSB). 2023a. “Fakten Zum Wohnungsmarkt.” https://www.bmwsb.bund.de/Webs/BMWSB/DE/themen/stadt-wohnen/wohnungswirtschaft/fakten-wohnungsmarkt/fakten-wohnungsmarkt-node.html (accessed September 2023).Search in Google Scholar
Federal Ministry for Housing, Urban Development and Building (BMWSB). 2023b. “Soziale Wohnraumförderung.” https://www.bmwsb.bund.de/Webs/BMWSB/DE/themen/stadt-wohnen/wohnraumfoerderung/soziale-wohnraumfoerderung/soziale-wohnraumfoerderung-node.html (accessed September 2023).Search in Google Scholar
Federal Ministry of Justice (FMJ). 2008. “Wohngeldgesetz (WoGG).” https://www.gesetze-im-internet.de/wogg/BJNR185610008.html#BJNR185610008BJNG000100000 (accessed September 2023).Search in Google Scholar
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. 2024. “Homeownership Rate in the united states (Rhorusq156n).” https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/RHORUSQ156N.Search in Google Scholar
Federal Statistical Office. 2023. “Zu- und fortzüge (über gemeindegrenzen) – jahressumme – regionale tiefe: Gemeinden – 2017–2021.” www.regionalstatistik.de.Search in Google Scholar
Federal Statistical Office. 2024. “Haushalte in Gebäuden mit Wohnraum (ohne Wohnheime) nach Anzahl in Eigentümerwohnungen, Eigentumsquote und Bundesländern 2022.” https://www.destatis.de/DE/Themen/Gesellschaft-Umwelt/Wohnen/Tabellen/tabelle-eigentumsquote.html.Search in Google Scholar
Gupta, A., V. Mittal, J. Peeters, and S. Van Nieuwerburgh. 2022. “Flattening the Curve: Pandemic-Induced Revaluation of Urban Real Estate.” Journal of Financial Economics 146 (2): 594–636. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2021.10.008. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304405X21004694 Search in Google Scholar
Hamann, S., A. Niebuhr, D. Roth, and G. Sieglen. 2023. “How Does the Covid-19 Pandemic Affect Regional Labor Markets and Why Do Large Cities Suffer Most?” Journal of Regional Science 63 (5): 1228–50. https://doi.org/10.1111/jors.12662. https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1111/jors.12662 Search in Google Scholar
Hirt, S. 2007. “The Devil Is in the Definitions: Contrasting American and German Approaches to Zoning.” Journal of the American Planning Association 73 (4): 436–50. https://doi.org/10.1080/01944360708978524.Search in Google Scholar
Internal Revenue Service (IRS). 2023. “Publication 936 – Home Mortgage Interest Deduction.” https://www.irs.gov/publications/p936.Search in Google Scholar
Kolbe, J., and M. Wüstemann. 2015. “Estimating the Value of Urban Green Space. Sonderforschungsbereich 649.” Ökonomisches Risiko 2, https://doi.org/10.18452/4559.Search in Google Scholar
Kosfeld, R., and A. Werner. 2012. “Deutsche Arbeitsmarktregionen – Neuabgrenzung nach den Kreisgebietsreformen 2007–2011.” Raumforschung und Raumordnung | Spatial Research and Planning 70 (1). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13147-011-0137-8. https://rur.oekom.de/index.php/rur/article/view/932 Search in Google Scholar
Liu, S., and Y. Su. 2021. “The Impact of the COVID-19 Pandemic on the Demand for Density: Evidence from the U.S. Housing Market.” Economics Letters 207: 110010. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2021.110010. https://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S0165176521002871 Search in Google Scholar
Mills, E. S. 1967. “An Aggregative Model of Resource Allocation in a Metropolitan Area.” The American Economic Review 57 (2): 197–210. http://www.jstor.org/stable/1821621.Search in Google Scholar
Muth, R. F. 1969. Cities and Housing: The Spatial Pattern of Urban Residential Land Use, 3rd ed. Chicago, Ill: University of Chicago Press.Search in Google Scholar
Nagler, M., J. Rincke, and E. Winkler. 2022. “How Much Do Workers Actually Value Working from Home?” https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=4279162.10.2139/ssrn.4279162Search in Google Scholar
National Association of Realtors (NAR). 2019. “2019 Home Buyers and Sellers Generational Trends Report.”. https://www.nar.realtor/sites/default/files/documents/2019-home-buyers-and-sellers-generational-trends-report-08-16-2019.pdf.Search in Google Scholar
National Association of Realtors (NAR). 2020. “2020 Home Buyers and Sellers Generational Trends Report.” https://www.nar.realtor/sites/default/files/documents/2020-generational-trends-report-03-05-2020.pdf.Search in Google Scholar
National Association of Realtors (NAR). 2024. “2024 Home Buyers and Sellers Generational Trends Report.” https://www.nar.realtor/sites/default/files/documents/2024-home-buyers-and-sellers-generational-trends-04-03-2024.pdf.Search in Google Scholar
NYC Housing Authority. 2024. “Section 8.” https://www.nyc.gov/site/nycha/section-8/about-section-8.page.Search in Google Scholar
Office, F. S. 2022. “Erwerbstätige nach Stellung im Beruf, Entfernung, Zeitaufwand und benutztem Verkehrsmittel für den Hinweg zur Arbeitsstätte 2020 in %.” https://www.destatis.de/DE/Themen/Arbeit/Arbeitsmarkt/Erwerbstaetigkeit/Tabellen/pendler1.html.Search in Google Scholar
Plenk, L. 2022. “Legal Mechanisms Impacting Urban Sprawl: A Comparison of the united states and germany.” Journal of Health, Environment and Education 14: 1–10, https://doi.org/10.18455/14001.Search in Google Scholar
Ramani, A., and N. Bloom. 2021. The Donut Effect of Covid-19 on Cities. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Technical Report w28876. http://www.nber.org/papers/w28876.pdf.10.3386/w28876Search in Google Scholar
RWI and ImmobilienScout24. 2022a. “RWI Real Estate Data – Apartments for Rent – sufRWI Real Estate Data – Wohnungsmiete – Suf.” https://fdz.rwi-essen.de/doi-detail/id-107807immoredwmsufv7.html.Search in Google Scholar
RWI and ImmobilienScout24. 2022b. “RWI Real Estate Data – Houses for Sale – sufRWI Real Estate Data – Hauskauf – Suf.” https://fdz.rwi-essen.de/doi-detail/id-107807immoredhksufv7.html.Search in Google Scholar
RWI and Microm. 2022. “RWI-GEO-GRID: Socio-Economic Data on Grid Level (Wave 12)RWI-GEO-GRID: Socio-Economic Data on Grid Level (Wave 12).” https://fdz.rwi-essen.de/doi-detail/id-107807micromv12.html.Search in Google Scholar
RWI and Microm. 2023. “Socio-economic data on grid level (wave 13)Sozioökonomische Daten auf Rasterebene (Welle 13).” https://fdz.rwi-essen.de/doi-detail/id-107807micromv13.html.Search in Google Scholar
Schäfer, P., and J. Hirsch. 2017. “Do Urban Tourism Hotspots affect Berlin housing Rents?” International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis 10 (2): 231–55. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJHMA-05-2016-0031.Search in Google Scholar
Tagesschau. 2024. “Zahl der Baugenehmigungen 2023 eingebrochen.” https://www.tagesschau.de/wirtschaft/baugenehmigungen-106.html.Search in Google Scholar
van Vuuren, A. 2023. “Is There a Diminishing Willingness to Pay for Consumption Amenities as a Result of the Covid-19 Pandemic?” Regional Science and Urban Economics 98: 103858. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2022.103858. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0166046222000965 Search in Google Scholar
© 2025 the author(s), published by De Gruyter, Berlin/Boston
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Original Articles
- A Re-Consideration of Money Demand Theory
- The Impact of COVID-19 on Real Estate Markets in Germany
- The Pass Through of Monetary Policy to Euro Area Bank Interest Rates
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Original Articles
- A Re-Consideration of Money Demand Theory
- The Impact of COVID-19 on Real Estate Markets in Germany
- The Pass Through of Monetary Policy to Euro Area Bank Interest Rates