Home Skill complementarity in production technology: New empirical evidence and implications
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Skill complementarity in production technology: New empirical evidence and implications

  • Andrey Stoyanov and Nick Zubanov ORCID logo EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: October 15, 2021

Abstract

Danish manufacturing firm data reveal that 1) industries differ in within-firm worker skill (= wage) dispersion, and 2) within-firm skill dispersion positively correlates with firm productivity in industries with higher average skill dispersion. We argue that these patterns reflect technological differences between industries: firms in the “skill complementarity” industries profit from hiring similarly able workers, while the “skill substitutability” firms thrive on skill differences. Our study produces a robust, data-driven and theoretically validated classification of industries into the complementarity and substitutability groups, unveils hitherto unnoticed technological heterogeneity between industries within the same economy, and illustrates its importance through simulations.

Appendix A

A.1 The model behind simulations in Section 4.4

Consider an economy with two perfectly competitive industry sectors, indexed by i = 1 , 2, with linear demand functions:

(10) Q i = a i b i p i

where Q i is the quantity of good i consumed, and a i > 0 and b i > 0 are the demand function parameters.

The output Y i in each sector is produced by combining two types of labor, A and B, using a production technology similar to that specified in equations (2) and (3) in the main text:

(11) Y i = L i L ˆ i

where L i = L i A + L i B is the total employment in sector i, L i k is the amount of type-k labor used in sector i, L ˆ i = θ i A s A ρ i + θ i B s B ρ i 1 ρ i is the labor efficiency term, θ i k = L i k L i is the share of type-k labor in total employment, ρ i is the parameter that captures the degree of complementarity between the two types of labor in sector i, and s k > 0 are the type-specific labor productivity parameters. Note that the total factor productivity in each sector is fixed to one, so that industries differ only in the degree of complementarity between the two types of labor, captured by parameters ρ i , and in the demand conditions, a i , b i . Each type of labor is supplied inelastically: there are L A and L B units of each type, and full employment.

Firms within each sector are symmetric. Given the production technologies defined above, firm j operating in industry i chooses the level of employment for each type of labor in order to maximize its profit function

π i j = p i Y i w A L i j A w B L i j B

where p i is the market price of a good produced by sector i, and w k is the wage rate earned by workers of type k.

Taking the first-order conditions of the profit function with respect to L i j A and L i j B and summing across all firms within an industry, we obtain the demand functions for each type of labor in each sector:

(12) p i Y i L i 1 + θ i n 1 ρ i L i L ˆ i s k ρ i s n ρ i = w k , n k

The marginal production costs in sector i are then equal to

(13) m c i = w A L i A + w B L i B Y i

The equilibrium in this simple model is defined as a set of resource allocations L i k , market prices p i , wages for each type of labor w k , output levels by sector Y i , and consumption of each good Q i such that, given production technologies and market demand functions:

  1. the labor markets clear

    (14) L 1 A + L 2 A = L A L 1 B + L 2 B = L B ,

  2. the goods markets clear

    (15) Y i = Q i ,

  3. firms maximize profits

    (16) p i = m c i .

Equilibrium conditions (10), (12), (14), (16), and (15) provide a system of twelve equations with twelve unknowns, p i , w k , Y i , Q i , L i A , L i B .

A.2 Additional figures and tables

Figure A1

Figure 3 replicated for different measures of skill complementarity.

Figure A2

Figure 3 replicated for different measures of within-firm skill dispersion.

Figure A3

Figure 3 replicated for the unrestricted version of equation (6).

Table A1

Estimation results by specification from unconstrained specification.

Measure of skill complementarity Measure of skill dispersion ρ H ρ L p-value for ρ H = ρ L Shares of industries with skill substitutability in the total

Output Employment # of firms
Panel A: estimation results for NLLS
PCA skill1 8.26 −0.45 0.00 0.728 0.700 0.678
skill2 2.30 −5.21 0.00 0.728 0.700 0.678
skill3 1.93 −2.24 0.02 0.728 0.700 0.678
skill4 2.06 −0.97 0.17 0.728 0.700 0.678
Impact skill1 3.99 −2.54 0.00 0.221 0.172 0.107
skill2 9.16 −8.39 0.00 0.221 0.172 0.107
skill3 6.88 −2.42 0.00 0.221 0.172 0.107
skill4 7.01 −3.20 0.00 0.221 0.172 0.107
Teamwork skill1 8.71 −0.78 0.00 0.754 0.739 0.731
skill2 8.88 −5.47 0.00 0.754 0.739 0.731
skill3 11.21 −2.20 0.00 0.754 0.739 0.731
skill4 5.52 −0.97 0.00 0.754 0.739 0.731
Contact skill1 6.52 −0.74 0.00 0.508 0.549 0.581
skill2 14.96 −5.36 0.00 0.508 0.549 0.581
skill3 9.37 −2.30 0.00 0.508 0.549 0.581
skill4 9.82 −3.13 0.00 0.508 0.549 0.581
Communication skill1 3.79 −2.63 0.00 0.204 0.151 0.090
skill2 8.57 −8.08 0.00 0.204 0.151 0.090
skill3 6.42 −2.39 0.00 0.204 0.151 0.090
skill4 6.63 −3.08 0.00 0.204 0.151 0.090
Panel B: estimation results for NLLS with control function
PCA skill1 1.39 −0.43 0.00 0.491 0.405 0.285
skill2 1.85 −5.77 0.00 0.491 0.405 0.285
skill3 1.59 −1.99 0.07 0.491 0.405 0.285
skill4 1.22 −2.64 0.04 0.491 0.405 0.285
Impact skill1 1.39 0.19 0.33 0.367 0.260 0.155
skill2 1.87 −4.50 0.00 0.367 0.260 0.155
skill3 1.50 −1.63 0.03 0.367 0.260 0.155
skill4 1.20 −2.41 0.08 0.367 0.260 0.155
Teamwork skill1 1.97 0.12 0.11 0.754 0.739 0.731
skill2 4.08 −3.45 0.00 0.754 0.739 0.731
skill3 3.12 −1.44 0.00 0.754 0.739 0.731
skill4 2.74 −0.56 0.00 0.754 0.739 0.731
Contact skill1 1.44 0.18 0.06 0.723 0.694 0.671
skill2 2.78 −3.58 0.00 0.723 0.694 0.671
skill3 2.03 −1.71 0.00 0.723 0.694 0.671
skill4 1.75 −0.75 0.09 0.723 0.694 0.671
Communication skill1 1.55 −0.58 0.06 0.204 0.151 0.090
skill2 2.57 −5.50 0.00 0.204 0.151 0.090
skill3 1.88 −1.75 0.00 0.204 0.151 0.090
skill4 1.55 −2.52 0.00 0.204 0.151 0.090
  1. Notes: Each line in the table presents the threshold regression estimation results for different measures of complementarity, skill dispersion, and econometric estimators. The first column describes the measure of skill complementarity used in the estimation, with PCA standing for the aggregate measure obtained by grouping all four measures into one using a principal component analysis (PCA). The second column describes the measure of skill dispersion: skill1 is measured as worker fixed effect from log wage equation; skill2 is worker fixed effects and observables (net of occupation effects) from log wage equation; skill3 is log wage net of firm fixed effect from log wage equation; skill4 is the log wage. The p-value for the test of ρ H = ρ L is obtained through bootstrap using 100 repetitions.

Table A2

Skill complementarity index by industry.

3-digit NACE industry code Industry name Skill complementarity index = frequency of being in the complementarity group
241 Manufacture of basic chemicals 1
242 Manufacture of pesticides and other agro-chemical products 1
243 Manufacture of paints, varnishes and similar coatings, printing ink and mastics 1
244 Manufacture of pharmaceuticals, medicinal chemicals and botanical products 1
246 Manufacture of other chemical products 1
247 Manufacture of man-made fibres 1
300 Manufacture of office machinery and computers 1
332 Manufacture of instruments and appliances for measuring, checking, testing, navigating and other purposes, except industrial process control equipment 1
245 Manufacture of soap and detergents, cleaning and polishing preparations, perfumes and toilet preparations 0.9
297 Manufacture of domestic appliances n.e.c. 0.9
311 Manufacture of electric motors, generators and transformers 0.9
312 Manufacture of electricity distribution and control apparatus 0.9
316 Manufacture of electrical equipment n.e.c. 0.9
313 Manufacture of insulated wire and cable 0.875
314 Manufacture of accumulators, primary cells and primary batteries 0.875
315 Manufacture of lighting equipment and electric lamps 0.8
351 Building and repairing of ships and boats 0.8
266 Manufacture of articles of concrete, plaster and cement 0.7
267 Cutting, shaping and finishing of stone 0.7
268 Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products 0.7
271 Manufacture of basic iron and steel and of ferro-alloys 0.7
272 Manufacture of tubes 0.7
273 Other first processing of iron and steel 0.7
274 Manufacture of basic precious and non-ferrous metals 0.7
275 Casting of metals 0.7
291 Manufacture of machinery for the production and use of mechanical power, except aircraft, vehicle and cycle engines 0.6
293 Manufacture of agricultural and forestry machinery 0.6
294 Manufacture of machine-tools 0.6
295 Manufacture of other special purpose machinery 0.6
331 Manufacture of medical and surgical equipment and orthopaedic appliances 0.6
152 Processing and preserving of fish and fish products 0.575
153 Processing and preserving of fruit and vegetables 0.575
154 Manufacture of vegetable and animal oils and fats 0.575
155 Manufacture of dairy products 0.575
156 Manufacture of grain mill products, starches and starch products 0.575
157 Manufacture of prepared animal feeds 0.575
262 Manufacture of non-refractory ceramic goods other than for construction purposes 0.5
263 Manufacture of ceramic tiles and flags 0.5
264 Manufacture of bricks, tiles and construction products 0.5
265 Manufacture of cement, lime and plaster 0.5
281 Manufacture of structural metal products 0.5
282 Manufacture of tanks, reservoirs and containers of metal; manufacture of central heating radiators and boilers 0.5
283 Manufacture of steam generators, except central heating hot water boilers 0.5
284 Forging, pressing, stamping and roll forming of metal; powder metallurgy 0.5
285 Treatment and coating of metals; general mechanical engineering 0.5
286 Manufacture of cutlery, tools and general hardware 0.5
287 Manufacture of other fabricated metal products 0.5
292 Manufacture of other general purpose machinery 0.5
342 Manufacture of bodies (coachwork) for motor vehicles; manufacture of trailers and semi-trailers 0.5
343 Manufacture of parts and accessories for motor vehicles and their engines 0.5
352 Manufacture of railway and tramway locomotives and rolling stock 0.5
353 Manufacture of aircraft and spacecraft 0.5
354 Manufacture of motorcycles and bicycles 0.5
355 Manufacture of other transport equipment n.e.c. 0.5
362 Manufacture of jewellery and related articles 0.5
366 Miscellaneous manufacturing n.e.c. 0.5
212 Manufacture of articles of paper and paperboard 0.4
261 Manufacture of glass and glass products 0.4
252 Manufacture of plastic products 0.3
201 Sawmilling and planing of wood; impregnation of wood 0.2
202 Manufacture of veneer sheets; manufacture of plywood, laminboard, particle board, fibre board and other panels and boards 0.2
203 Manufacture of builders’ carpentry and joinery 0.2
204 Manufacture of wooden containers 0.2
205 Manufacture of other products of wood; manufacture of articles of cork. straw and plaiting materials 0.2
361 Manufacture of furniture 0.2
251 Manufacture of rubber products 0.1
151 Production, processing and preserving of meat and meat products 0
174 Manufacture of made-up textile articles, except apparel 0
175 Manufacture of other textiles 0
177 Manufacture of knitted and crocheted articles 0
182 Manufacture of other wearing apparel and accessories 0
211 Manufacture of pulp, paper and paperboard 0
221 Publishing 0
222 Printing and service activities related to printing 0

References

Abowd, J., and F. Kramarz. 1999. “High Wage Workers and High Wage Firms.” Econometrica 67 (2): 251–333. 10.3386/w4917Search in Google Scholar

Adelman, M. A. 1969. “Comment on the H Concentration Measure as a Numbers Equivalent.” Review of Economics and Statistics 51: 99–102. 10.2307/1926955Search in Google Scholar

Arranz-Aperte, L. 2014. “Chapter The Impact of Wage Dispersion on Labor Productivity: Evidence from Finnish Workers.” In New Analyses of Worker Well-Being, edited by S. Polachek and K. Tatsiramos, Vol. 38 of Research in Labor Economics. Emerald Group Publishing Limited. 10.1108/S0147-9121(2013)0000038003Search in Google Scholar

Bombardini, M., G. Gallipoli, and G. Pupato. 2012. “Skill Dispersion and Trade Flows.” American Economic Review 102 (5): 2327–2348. 10.3386/w15097Search in Google Scholar

Grossman, G., and G. Maggi. 2000. “Diversity and Trade.” American Economic Review 90 (5): 1255–1275. 10.3386/w6741Search in Google Scholar

Grund, C., and N. Westergaard-Nielsen. 2008. “The Dispersion of Employees’ Wage Increases and Firm Performance.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 61 (4): 485–501. 10.1177/001979390806100403Search in Google Scholar

Hansen, B. 1999. “Threshold Effects in Non-dynamic Panels: Estimation, Testing, and Inference.” Journal of Econometrics 93 (2): 345–368. 10.1016/S0304-4076(99)00025-1Search in Google Scholar

Havranek, T., Z. Irsova, L. Laslopova, and O. Zeynalova. 2020. The Elasticity of Substitution Between Skilled and Unskilled Labor: A Meta-Analysis. MPRA Paper No. 102598. https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/102598/. 10.31222/osf.io/7z2uhSearch in Google Scholar

Hunnes, A. 2009. “Internal Wage Dispersion and Firm Performance: White-collar Evidence.” International Journal of Manpower 30 (8): 776–796. 10.1108/01437720911004425Search in Google Scholar

Iranzo, S., F. Schivardi, and E. Tosetti. 2006. Skill Dispersion and Firm Productivity: An Analysis with Employer-Employee Matched Data. Bank of Italy Economic Research Paper No. 577. 10.2139/ssrn.895516Search in Google Scholar

Iranzo, S., F. Schivardi, and E. Tosetti. 2008. “Skill Dispersion and Firm Productivity: An Analysis with Employer-Employee Matched Data.” Journal of Labor Economics 26 (2): 247–285. 10.1086/587091Search in Google Scholar

Jirjahn, U., and K. Kraft. 2007. “Intra-firm Wage Dispersion and Firm Performance – Is There a Uniform Relationship?” Kyklos 60 (2): 231–253. 10.1111/j.1467-6435.2007.00370.xSearch in Google Scholar

Kahane, L., N. Longley, and R. Simmons. 2013. “The Effects of Coworker Heterogeneity on Firm-Level Output: Assessing the Impacts of Cultural and Language Diversity in the National Hockey League.” Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (1): 302–314. 10.1162/REST_a_00221Search in Google Scholar

Konings, J., and S. Vanormelingen. 2015. “The Impact of Training on Productivity and Wages: Firm-Level Evidence.” Review of Economics and Statistics 97 (2): 485–497. 10.1162/REST_a_00460Search in Google Scholar

Kremer, M. 1993. “The O-Ring Theory of Economic Development.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3): 551–575. 10.2307/2118400Search in Google Scholar

Lallemand, T., R. Plasman, and F. Rycx. 2009. “The Structure of Wages: An International Comparison.” In Wage Structure and Firm Productivity in Belgium, edited by E. Lazear and K. Shaw Chapter, 179–215. The University of Chicago Press. 10.7208/chicago/9780226470511.003.0007Search in Google Scholar

Lazear, E. 1999. “Globalization and the Market for Team-Mates.” Economic Journal 109: C15–C40. 10.1111/1468-0297.00414Search in Google Scholar

Lazear, E., and K. Shaw. 2009. “The Structure of Wages: An International Comparison.” In Wage Structure, Raises, and Mobility: International Comparisons of the Structure of Wages Within and Across Firms, edited by E. Lazear and K. Shaw Chapter, 1–57. The University of Chicago Press. 10.7208/chicago/9780226470511.001.0001Search in Google Scholar

Lee, K.-W., B. Lev, and G. Yeo. 2008. “Executive Pay Dispersion, Corporate Governance and Firm Performance.” Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 30: 315–338. 10.1007/s11156-007-0053-8Search in Google Scholar

Liu, J.-T., M.-W. Tsou, and P. Wang. 2010. “Workforce Composition and Firm Productivity: Evidence from Taiwan.” Economic Inquiry 48 (4): 1032–1047. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00232.xSearch in Google Scholar

Mahy, B., F. Rycx, and M. Volral. 2011a. “Does Wage Dispersion Make All Firms Productive?” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 58 (4): 455–489. 10.1111/j.1467-9485.2011.00555.xSearch in Google Scholar

Mahy, B., F. Rycx, and M. Volral. 2011b. “Wage Dispersion and Firm Productivity in Different Working Environments.” British Journal of Industrial Relations 49 (3): 460–485. 10.1111/j.1467-8543.2009.00775.xSearch in Google Scholar

Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts. 1990. “The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technology, Strategy, and Organization.” American Economic Review 80 (3): 511–528. Search in Google Scholar

Olley, S., and A. Pakes. 1996. “The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry.” Econometrica 64 (6): 1263–1297. 10.3386/w3977Search in Google Scholar

Parrotta, P., D. Pozzoli, and M. Pytlikova. 2014. “Labor Diversity and Firm Productivity.” European Economic Review 66 (C): 144–179. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2013.12.002Search in Google Scholar

Prat, A. 2002. “Should a Team Be Homogeneous?” European Economic Review 46 (7): 1187–1207. 10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00165-9Search in Google Scholar

Rosen, S. 1982. “Authority, Control, and the Distribution of Earnings.” Bell Journal of Economics 13 (2): 311–323. 10.2307/j.ctv1kz4h99.13Search in Google Scholar

Shore, L., A. Randel, B. Chung, M. Dean, K. Ehrhart, and G. Singh. 2011. “Inclusion and Diversity in Work Groups: A Review and Model for Future Research.” Journal of Management 37 (4): 1262–1289. 10.1177/0149206310385943Search in Google Scholar

Skans, O., P.-A. Edin, and B. Holmund. 2009. “Wage Dispersion Between and Within Plants: Sweden 1985–2000.” In The Structure of Wages: An International Comparison, edited by E. Lazear and K. Shaw. The University of Chicago Press. Search in Google Scholar

Smedley, T. 2014. “The Evidence is Growing – There Really Is a Business Case for Diversity.” Financial Times May 15. Search in Google Scholar

Wingender, A. 2015. “Skill complementarity and the dual economy.” European Economic Review 74: 269–285. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2014.12.006Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2021-10-15
Published in Print: 2022-05-31

© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 23.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/ger-2020-0102/html
Scroll to top button