Home Stable Matching with Double Infinity of Workers and Firms
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Stable Matching with Double Infinity of Workers and Firms

  • Matías Fuentes EMAIL logo and Fernando Tohmé
Published/Copyright: December 5, 2018

Abstract

In this paper we analyze the existence of stable matchings in a two-sided large market in which workers are assigned to firms. The market has a continuum of workers while the set of firms is countably infinite. We show that, under certain reasonable assumptions on the preference correspondences, stable matchings not only exist but are also Pareto optimal.

JEL Classification: C71; C78

Appendix

A Proof of Theorem 4

We now turn to the proof of the theorem. The strategy is to construct a sequence of large economies with finitely many firms such that in every case there is a stable matching. Then, by a limit argument we obtain a stable matching for the original economy. In doing so, we structure the proof in three parts: First we define a sequence of truncated versions of the original economy. Second we show that each of them has a stable matching and third we study the limit point of the ensuing sequence of stable matchings and show it to be a stable matching of the original economy.

First part: Specification of a sequence of economies with finitely many firms.

For every natural number n, we define the set Fn:=f1,f2,...,fn and F˜n:=Fn. It is clear that F˜nF˜n+1F˜n+2..., F˜=n=1F˜n and |F˜n|=n+1. The correspondence Cf:χχ is that of Section 2 for fF˜n.

The preference of the workers are given by the restricted preference P|F˜n:{1,...,n+1}F˜n. That is to say P|F˜n and P order the firms in F˜n in the same way.

For every fF˜n the measures Dn,fM and Dn,fM are defined as

Dn,fM:=PPfF˜n,fPfMf(ΘP)

and

Dn,fM:=PPfF˜n,fPfMf(ΘP).

Hence, the truncated large economy is specified by (G,F˜n,(ΘP)PP,(Cf)fF˜n) and we obtain a sequence of large economies with finite sets of firms directed by inclusion {G,F˜n,(ΘP)PP,(Cf)fF˜n}n1.

Second part: Each of the terms of the sequence has a stable matching.

It is easy to check that Assumptions 1 and 2 hold in every economy (G,F˜n,(ΘP)PP,(Cf)fF˜n). Consequently, by Theorem 2 of Che, Kim, and Kojima (forthcoming), there exists a stable matching Mn=MfnfF˜nχn+1 in every (G,F˜n,(ΘP)PP,(Cf)fF˜n)[4]. We expand it to the product space χ|F˜| while still writing it as Mn=MfnfF˜.[5] Let us recall that χ|F˜| is a subset of the topological dual of C(Θ)|F˜| given by M|F˜|.

Let us consider the set NffF˜M|F˜|:fF˜Nf=G. It can be easily checked that it is norm-bounded and by Alaoglu’s Theorem (Rudin 1991) it is weak-compact. Since Mn belongs to the above set  for every n, there exists a subsequence MnkkK, where K is a subset of the natural numbers, converging to M in the weak-topology. Since a sequence in a product space converges if and only if the projection of each component converges (Kelly 1955, p. 91), we have a limit M=MffF˜.

Third part: M is a stable matching.

Since for every kK, fF˜Mfnk=G and χ is weak-closed, we have that fF˜Mf=G, hence M is a matching. We now show that it is stable:

  1. Let fF˜ and PP such that Pf. There exists n0 such that fF˜n0. There exists k0K such that for all kk0, F˜n0F˜nk. Since Mnk=MfnkfF˜ is a stable matching we have that MfnkΘP=0 for all kk0. Hence, MfΘP=0.

  2. Let fF˜. There exists n0 such that fF˜n0. There exists k0K such that for all kk0, F˜n0F˜nk. Since Mnk=MfnkfF˜ is a stable matching we have that MfnkCfMfnk for all kK. By Assumption 2., MfCfMf.

We have proven that the matching M satisfies individual rationality. It only remains to show that there is no blocking coalition. We proceed by contradiction. Suppose that there exists fF and Mfχ such that MfDfM, MfCfMfMf and MfCfMfMf. It is clear that MfMfMf, whence MfχMfMf. By (ii) above, MfCfMf and hence, MfCfMfχMfMf. Consequently, by the revealed preference condition, MfCfMfMf, a contradiction.

B Proof of Proposition 5

First of all, we claim that[6]

(1)PPfF˜,fPfˉMf(ΘPS)PPfF˜,fPfˉMf(ΘPS)

for all Sσ(Θ) and all fˉF˜ is equivalent to saying that

(2)fF˜,fPfˉMf(ΘPS)fF˜,fPfˉMf(ΘPS)

for all Sσ(Θ), for all fˉF˜ and all PP. Indeed, for Sσ(Θ), one has that SΘP belongs to σ(Θ) since ΘP is assumed measurable. Then, since SΘP does not meet ΘP for PʹP it follows that (1) implies (2). The converse is immediate.

We proceed by contradiction. Let us suppose that there exists M  such that MFM and MΘM. Consequently there exists fF such that MfMf. For a given preference PP we denote the immediate predecessor of f as fP.[7]. Since MΘM then, for each fˉF˜, one has

fF˜,fPfˉMf(ΘPS)fF˜,fPfˉMf(ΘPS)

for all Sσ(Θ) and PP. In particular for fP

fF˜,fPfPMf(ΘPS)fF˜,fPfPMf(ΘPS)

for all Sσ(Θ)

Which is equivalent to

(3)fF˜,fPfMf(ΘPS)fF˜,fPfMf(ΘPS)

for all Sσ(Θ)

Given PP we have

fF˜Mf(ΘPS)=G(ΘPS)=fF˜Mf(ΘPS)for allSσ(Θ)

which can be rewritten as

fF˜,ffMf(ΘPS)+fF˜,ffMf(ΘPS)=fF˜,ffMf(ΘPS)+fF˜,ffMf(ΘPS)

for all Sσ(Θ).

We claim that fF˜,ffMf(ΘPS)fF˜,ffMf(ΘPS) for all Sσ(Θ). Otherwise, from the previous equality one deduces that fF˜,ffMf(ΘPS)<fF˜,ffMf(ΘPS) for some Sσ(Θ) which contradicts (3). Summing over P,

PPfF˜,ffMf(ΘPS)PPfF˜,ffMf(ΘPS)

for all Sσ(Θ)

Since MfMf and MfDf(M) we have a contradiction with the fact that M is a stable matching. Consequently, M is weakly Pareto efficient.

Now, if |Cf(X)|=1 for all Xχ and we assume that M is not Pareto efficient, then there is another matching M  and FF˜ such that MM, MFM and MΘM. Consequently, there exists fF such that MfMf which means that Mf=Cf(MfMf). Then MfMf, whence MfMf which contradicts the fact that M is a stable matching.

Acknowledgements

This paper was partially developed while the first author was a visiting scholar at Université Paris 1-Pantheón Sorbonne. The hospitality of the institution and the support of EEyN-UNSAM are gratefully acknowledged.

References

Azevedo, E., and J. Leshno. 2016. “A Supply and Demand Framework for Two-Sided Matching Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 124: 1235–1268.10.1086/687476Search in Google Scholar

Blair, C. 1988. “The Lattice Structure of the Set of Stable Matching with Multiple Partners”. Mathematics of Operations Research 13: 619–628.10.1287/moor.13.4.619Search in Google Scholar

Che, Y.-K., J. Kim, and F. Kojima. forthcoming. “Stable Matching in Large Economies”. Econometrica.10.3982/ECTA13547Search in Google Scholar

Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. New Haven: Cowles Foundation Monographs Series.Search in Google Scholar

Dunford, N., and J. Schwartz. 1958. Linear Operators. Part I. New York: Interscience.Search in Google Scholar

Echenique, F., and J. Pereyra. 2016. “Strategic Complementarities and Unraveling in Matching Markets.” Theoretical Economics 11: 1–39.10.3982/TE1831Search in Google Scholar

Economic Sciences Prize Committee of the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences: “Scientific Background Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2012: Stable Allocations and the Practice of Market Design.” http://www. nobelprize.org/nobel\_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2012/advanced-economicsciences2012.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Gale, D., and L. Shapley. 1962. “ College Admissions and the Stability of Marriage”. American Mathematical Monthly 69: 9–15.10.1080/00029890.1962.11989827Search in Google Scholar

Gretsky, N., J. Ostroy, and W. Zame. 1992. “The Nonatomic Assignment Model”. Economic Theory 2: 103–127.10.1007/BF01213255Search in Google Scholar

Gretsky, N., J. Ostroy, and W. Zame. 1999. “Perfect Competition in the Continuous Assignment Model.” Journal of Economic Theory 88: 60–118.10.1006/jeth.1999.2540Search in Google Scholar

Hart, S., W. Hildenbrand, and E. Kohlberg. 1974. ““On Equilibrium Allocations as Distributions on the Commodity Space".” Journal of Mathematical Economics 1: 159–166.10.1016/0304-4068(74)90006-8Search in Google Scholar

Hatfield, J., and S. Kominers. 2015. “Multilateral Matching.” Journal of Economic Theory 156: 175–206.10.1016/j.jet.2014.04.009Search in Google Scholar

Hatfield, J., and P. Milgrom. 2005. “Matching with Contracts.” American Economic Review 95: 913–935.10.1257/0002828054825466Search in Google Scholar

Kaneko, M., and M. Wooders. 1986. “The Core of a Game with a Continuum of Players and Finite Coalitions: The Model and Some Results.” Mathematical Social Sciences 12: 105–137.10.1016/0165-4896(86)90032-6Search in Google Scholar

Kaneko, M., and M. Wooders. 1996. “The Nonemptiness of the f -Core of a Game Without Side Payments.” International Journal of Game Theory 25: 245–258.10.1007/BF01247105Search in Google Scholar

Kelly, J. 1955. General Topology. New York: Van Nostrand.Search in Google Scholar

Kojima, F., and M. Ünver. 2014. “The ‘Boston’ School-choice Mechanism: an Axiomatic Approach.” Economic Theory 55: 515–544.10.1007/s00199-013-0769-8Search in Google Scholar

Mas-Colell, A., and W. Zame. 1991 “Equilibrium Theory in Infinite Dimensional Spaces”. In Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. IV, edited by W. Hildenbrand, H. Sonnenschein, 1836–1898. Amsterdam: North-Holland.10.1016/S1573-4382(05)80009-8Search in Google Scholar

Nöldeke, G., and L. Samuelson. 2017 “The implementation duality”. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1993R.Search in Google Scholar

Roth, A. 1984. “The Evolution of the Labor Market for Medical Interns and Residents: a Case Study in Game Theory.” Journal of Political Economy 92: 991–1016.10.1086/261272Search in Google Scholar

Rudin, W. 1991. Functional Analysis. Boston MA: McGraw-Hill.Search in Google Scholar

Schaefer, H. H., and M. P. Wolf. 1999. Topological Vector Spaces, 2nd ed. New York and Berlin: Springer-Verlag.10.1007/978-1-4612-1468-7Search in Google Scholar

Sönmez, T., and M. Ünver. 2011. “Matching, Allocation, and Exchange of Discrete Resources.” In Handbook of Social Economics, edited by J. Benhabib, A. Bisin, and M. Jackson. Amsterdam: North-Holland.10.1016/B978-0-444-53187-2.00017-6Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2018-12-05

© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 9.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2018-0015/html
Scroll to top button