Abstract
Studies measuring barriers to firm growth assume economies are closed, ignoring information on firm exports. We argue that this information is key to interpreting data and improving the accuracy of model predictions. To do this, we develop a dynamic model with export and domestic barriers. We show theoretically that the closed economy model underestimates barriers and amplifies counterfactuals. By calibrating the model to a set of European countries, we find that the quantitative difference is significant: for example, the closed economy model fails to see that Italian firms are very efficient exporters but poor innovators, and instead concludes that they are mediocre innovators. In terms of predictions, the closed economy model delivers an elasticity of welfare to innovation costs between 31 and 64 percent larger than the open economy model.
Acknowledgement
We thank Tim Kehoe, Kim Ruhl, Victor Rios Rull, Fernando Alvarez, Ariel Burstein, Richard Rogerson, Marina Azzimonti, Klaus Desmet, Juan Carlos Hallak, Gueorgui Kambourov (the editor) and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. We benefited from talks at ASU, San Andres, WVU, Di Tella, ITAM, the conferences REDG 2012, SED 2012 and Mid West Trade 2012. Loris Rubini gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation (ECO2008-01300 and ECO2011-27014). All errors are our own.
Appendices
A The endogenous distribution of firms
Define
Taking limits as
For small dt, the following holds:
Thus,
Note that in steady state
Ignoring all terms with dt elevated to a power larger than 1,
Cancelling terms and dividing by dt,
Define the steady state distribution as
To solve, use the border condition μ(1) = M. For exporters
To solve, use the border condition μ(zx) = μd(zx), where μd(zx) is the measure of non exporters that reach the export threshold.
The solution to these distributions works as follows. Start with the exporter distribution. The differential equation can be written as
where g(z) = gx for exporters and gd(z) for non exporters. For exporters, integrating on both sides,
where Cx is the constant of integration, and is determined using the border condition. Taking exponentials yields the distribution of exporters.
For non exporters, we can only integrate both sides of (28) given our guess for the growth rates. The equation becomes
Integrating on both sides,
where Cd is the constant of integration and is determined using the border condition μ(1) = 1 (the distribution is normalized by the measure of entrants M). Taking exponentials yields the distribution of non exporters.
B Productivity
The goal is to derive the reduced form for aggregate output
where
Labor used in production is
From trade balance,
where
Since
where
Next consider the price Pj. By definition,
Thus,
Rearranging,
where
C Proof of Proposition 2
Proof.
Using equation (15) evaluated at z = 1 and using the free-entry condition,
Exporter profits are
where Dj = 1 + τxj. Thus,
Rearrange the above equation to introduce the growth rate gx into it. To do so, multiply both sides by
Using equation (12) on the left hand side of the above equation,
To introduce
Introducing the last expression in equation (30) and simplifying,
From free entry in the closed economy,
Replacing Dj = 1 + τxj in (31), we obtain (22). Since profits are always positive and by Proposition 1, gxj > gdj(1), the right hand side of the above equation is positive. Thus, it must be the case that
D Proof of Corollary 1
Taking the difference of (20) for the two countries and reorganizing:
where
Because of the definition of exporters’s profits
Using the optimal innovation policy of the exporter
Therefore:
Similarly,
where ȃ
where
E Proof of Proposition 5
When κx = 0, given the closed form solution for the variables in equilibrium derived in the main section of the paper, and using trade balance, wages are
To solve this, we need to know the value of πd. Notice that
where
Introducing in this expression the value for w defines the following implicit function
Next we build towards showing that
We first show that
Lemma 1
If σ < 3/2
Proof.
Using the implicit function theorem, we show that if σ < 3/2 then
Define
Then the equation that defines
The implicit function theorem says
It is easy to check that
The first term on the third line comes from rearranging the expression F. The second term comes from the expressions derived previously for πx/w and the equilibrium value for gx.
Multiplying the equation by κI gives
⊡
We use the lemma for the proof of the proposition. The proposition says
To prove it, we proceed by contradiction. So suppose this is not true. Then if
From the definition of πx,
From trade balance,
We know that
F The firm size distributions in the data

Firm size distributions.

Exporters’ distributions.

Non-exporters’ distributions.
G Fit of the approximation
Recall that our solution for the non exporter growth rate involves a differential equation with no closed form solution. Since we need a closed form to derive the distribution of firms, we approximate the non exporter with the following functional form
In this section, we discuss the goodness of this fit. Table 17 shows the values we compute for the variables a, b, c, and d for each country. Figure 12 through Figure 16 show how good this approximation is for the growth rates and the non exporter value function.
Fitted values.
Country | a | b | c | d |
---|---|---|---|---|
France | 39.93 | 44.58 | −54.27 | 14.69 |
Germany | 23.39 | 66.24 | −62.75 | 15.83 |
Italy | −20.83 | 275.59 | −296.97 | 91.45 |
Spain | 36.33 | 50.34 | −56.99 | 15.17 |
UK | 42.65 | 31.97 | −47.01 | 13.80 |

France.

Germany.

Italy.

Spain.

UK.
H Alternative values of σ
Changing σ does not affect the computed values of the costs κI and κx, and only affects the estimates of τx. Table 18 shows how these values change.
Estimates of 1 + τx under different specifications of σ.
σ | 4.00 | 5.00 | 6.00 |
---|---|---|---|
France | 1.00 | 1.00 | 1.00 |
Germany | 1.00 | 1.00 | 1.00 |
Italy | 0.93 | 0.92 | 0.92 |
Spain | 1.69 | 1.42 | 1.30 |
UK | 0.88 | 0.92 | 0.94 |
Notice that when changing σ both the elasticity of substitution and a parameter that affects firm productivity are changing. This assumption follows Atkeson and Burstein (2010) and greatly simplifies the analysis by making profits linear in productivity.
There is no reason to believe this result would change if σ did not affect firm productivity, since one of the calibration targets is the trade volume. To see this, consider the result in Rubini (2014) that the effect of a larger σ is to amplify the share of imports within the economy, in a setting with innovation where σ does not affect the productivity of a firm. Intuitively, a larger σ increases the elasticity of substitution between domestic and imported goods, driving consumers to purchase more imports that are relatively cheaper. Given that the export share is a target in the calibration, this would require a larger τ to offset this change. There is no reason to expect additional first order effects. It is not clear whether this bias would be larger for Germany or the other countries, having little effect on the relative cost, as in the present case.
References
Acemoglu, D., and D. Cao. 2015. “Innovation by Entrants and Incumbents.” Journal of Economic Theory 157 (C): 255–294.10.1016/j.jet.2015.01.001Search in Google Scholar
Altomonte, C., and T. Aquilante. 2012. “The EU-EFIGE BRUEGEL-UNICREDIT Dataset.” Tech. rep., Bruegel Working Paper.Search in Google Scholar
Atkeson, A., and A. T. Burstein. 2010. “Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade.” Journal of Political Economy 118 (3): 433–484.10.1086/653690Search in Google Scholar
Bernard, A. B., and J. B. Jensen. 1999. “Exceptional Exporter Performance: Cause, Effect, or Both?” Journal of International Economics 47 (1): 1–25.10.1016/S0022-1996(98)00027-0Search in Google Scholar
Bhattacharya, D., N. Guner, and G. Ventura. 2013. “Distortions, Endogenous Managerial Skills and Productivity Differences.” Review of Economic Dynamics 16 (1): 11–25.10.1016/j.red.2012.10.001Search in Google Scholar
Brooks, W., and A. Dovis. 2011. “Trade Liberalization with Endogenous Borrowing Constraints.” Tech. rep.Search in Google Scholar
Brooks, W., and J. Wang. 2017. “The Aggregate Effects of Firm-Level Trade Distortions.” Tech. rep.Search in Google Scholar
Bustos, P. 2011. “Trade Liberalization, Exports, and Technology Upgrading: Evidence on the Impact of Mercosur on Argentinian Firms.” American Economic Review 101 (1): 304–340.10.1257/aer.101.1.304Search in Google Scholar
Caliendo, L., F. Monte, and E. Rossi-Hansberg. 2015. “The Anatomy of French Production Hierarchies.” Journal of Political Economy 123 (4): 809–852.10.1086/681641Search in Google Scholar
Caliendo, L., and E. Rossi-Hansberg. 2012. “The Impact of Trade on Organization and Productivity.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (3): 1393–1467.10.1093/qje/qjs016Search in Google Scholar
Caselli, F., and W. J. I. Coleman. 2001. “Cross-Country Technology Diffusion: The Case of Computers.” American Economic Review 91 (2): 328–335.10.1257/aer.91.2.328Search in Google Scholar
Costantini, J., and M. Melitz. 2008. “The Dynamics of Firm-Level Adjustment to Trade Liberalization.” In The Organization of Firms in a Global Economy, edited by E. Helpman, D. Marin, and T. Verdier. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Cubas, G., B. Ravikumar, and G. Ventura. 2016. “Talent, Labor Quality, and Economic Development.” Review of Economic Dynamics 21: 160–181.10.1016/j.red.2015.06.004Search in Google Scholar
De Loecker, J. 2007. “Do Exports Generate Higher Productivity? Evidence from Slovenia.” Journal of International Economics 73 (1): 69–98.10.1016/j.jinteco.2007.03.003Search in Google Scholar
Demidova, S., and A. Rodríguez-Clare. 2009. “Trade Policy Under Firm-Level Heterogeneity in a Small Economy.” Journal of International Economics 78 (1): 100–112.10.1016/j.jinteco.2009.02.009Search in Google Scholar
Eaton, J., and S. Kortum. 2002. “Technology, Geography, and Trade.” Econometrica 70: 1741–1779.10.1111/1468-0262.00352Search in Google Scholar
Erosa, A., T. Koreshkova, and D. Restuccia. 2010. “How Important is Human Capital? A Quantitative Theory Assessment of World Income Inequality.” Review of Economic Studies 77 (4): 1421–1449.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2010.00610.xSearch in Google Scholar
Eslava, M., A. C. Fieler, and D. Y. Xu. 2015. “(Indirect) Input Linkages.” American Economic Review 105 (5): 662–666.10.1257/aer.p20151122Search in Google Scholar
Gabaix, X. 2011. “The Granular Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations.” Econometrica 79: 733–772.10.3982/ECTA8769Search in Google Scholar
Goldberg, P., A. Khandelwal, N. Pavcnik, and P. Topalova. 2009. “Trade Liberalization and New Imported Inputs.” American Economic Review 99 (2): 494–500.10.1257/aer.99.2.494Search in Google Scholar
Goldberg, P. K., A. K. Khandelwal, N. Pavcnik, and P. Topalova. 2010. “Imported Intermediate Inputs and Domestic Product Growth: Evidence from India.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (4): 1727–1767.10.1162/qjec.2010.125.4.1727Search in Google Scholar
Gopinath, G., Ş. Kalemli-Özcan, L. Karabarbounis, and C. Villegas-Sanchez. 2017. “Capital Allocation and Productivity in South Europe.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132 (4): 1915–1967.10.1093/qje/qjx024Search in Google Scholar
Griffith, R., R. Harrison, and J. V. Reenen. 2006. “How Special is the Special Relationship? Using the Impact of U.S. R&D Spillovers on U.K. Firms as a Test of Technology Sourcing.” American Economic Review 96 (5): 1859–1875.10.1257/aer.96.5.1859Search in Google Scholar
Guadalupe, M., O. Kuzmina, and C. Thomas. 2012. “Innovation and Foreign Ownership.” American Economic Review 102 (7): 3594–3627.10.1257/aer.102.7.3594Search in Google Scholar
Haltiwanger, J., R. S. Jarmin, and J. Miranda. 2013. “Who Creates Jobs? Small Versus Large Versus Young.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (2): 347–361.10.1162/REST_a_00288Search in Google Scholar
Hsieh, C.-T., and P. J. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 1403–1448.10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1403Search in Google Scholar
Hsieh, C.-T., and P. J. Klenow. 2014. “The Life Cycle of Plants in India and Mexico*.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (3): 1035–1084.10.1093/qje/qju014Search in Google Scholar
Impullitti, G., A. A. Irarrazabal, and L. D. Opromolla. 2013. “A Theory of Entry into and Exit from Export Markets.” Journal of International Economics 90 (1): 75–90.10.1016/j.jinteco.2012.11.005Search in Google Scholar
Kambourov, G. 2009. “Labour Market Regulations and the Sectoral Reallocation of Workers: The Case of Trade Reforms.” Review of Economic Studies 76 (4): 1321–1358.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2009.00552.xSearch in Google Scholar
Khan, A., and B. Ravikumar. 2002. “Costly Technology Adoption and Capital Accumulation.” Review of Economic Dynamics 5 (2): 489–502.10.1006/redy.2002.0167Search in Google Scholar
Luttmer, E. G. J. 2007. “Selection, Growth, and the Size Distribution of Firms.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (3): 1103–1144.10.1162/qjec.122.3.1103Search in Google Scholar
Luttmer, E. G. J. 2010. “Models of Growth and Firm Heterogeneity.” Annual Reviews of Economics 2: 547–576.10.1146/annurev.economics.102308.124410Search in Google Scholar
McDaniel, C. 2007. “Average Tax Rates on Consumption, Investment, Labor and Capital in the OECD 1950–2003.” Tech. rep.Search in Google Scholar
Melitz, M. J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity.” Econometrica 71 (6): 1695–1725.10.1111/1468-0262.00467Search in Google Scholar
Newman, C., J. Rand, and F. Tarp. 2013. “Trade Liberalization, Supply Chains and Productivity.” Tech. rep.Search in Google Scholar
Pavcnik, N. 2002. “Trade Liberalization, Exit, and Productivity Improvement: Evidence from Chilean Plants.” Review of Economic Studies 69 (1): 245–276.10.1111/1467-937X.00205Search in Google Scholar
Piguillem, F., and L. Rubini. 2017. “Do Non-Exporters Lose from Lower Trade Costs?” Tech. rep.Search in Google Scholar
Ranasinghe, A. 2014. “Impact of Policy Distortions on Firm-Level Innovation, Productivity Dynamics, and TFP.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 46: 114–129.10.1016/j.jedc.2014.06.017Search in Google Scholar
Ranasinghe, A. 2017. “Innovation, Firm Size and the Canada-U.S. Productivity Gap.” Tech. rep.10.2139/ssrn.3035655Search in Google Scholar
Restuccia, D., and R. Rogerson. 2008. “Policy Distortions and Aggregate Productivity with Heterogeneous Plants.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4): 707–720.10.1016/j.red.2008.05.002Search in Google Scholar
Rubini, L. 2014. “Innovation and the Trade Elasticity.” Journal of Monetary Economics 66 (C): 32–46.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2014.04.002Search in Google Scholar
Rubini, L., K. Desmet, F. Piguillem, and A. Crespo. 2012. “Breaking Down the Barriers to Firm Growth in Europe: The Fourth EFIGE Policy Report. No. 18.” Bruegel Institute, Blue Print.Search in Google Scholar
Topalova, P., and A. Khandelwal. 2011. “Trade Liberalization and Firm Productivity: The Case of India.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 93 (3): 995–1009.10.1162/REST_a_00095Search in Google Scholar
Trefler, D. 2004. “The Long and Short of the Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement.” American Economic Review 94 (4): 870–895.10.1257/0002828042002633Search in Google Scholar
Tybout, J. R. 2000. “Manufacturing Firms in Developing Countries: How Well Do They Do, and Why?” Journal of Economic Literature 38 (1): 11–44.10.1257/jel.38.1.11Search in Google Scholar
Van Biesebroeck, J. 2005. “Exporting Raises Productivity in Sub-Saharan African Manufacturing Firms.” Journal of International Economics 67 (2): 373–391.10.1016/j.jinteco.2004.12.002Search in Google Scholar
Waugh, M. E. 2010. “International Trade and Income Differences.” American Economic Review 100 (5): 2093–2124.10.1257/aer.100.5.2093Search in Google Scholar
Yan-Aw, B., M. J. Roberts, and D. Y. Xu. 2011. “R&D Investments, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics.” American Economic Review 101 (4): 1312–1344.10.1257/aer.101.4.1312Search in Google Scholar
Supplementary Material
The online version of this article offers supplementary material (DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bejm-2018-0003).
©2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontiers
- The Precautionary Saving Effect of Government Consumption
- Advanced
- Optimal taxation under equilibrium unemployment and economic profits
- Labor supply, income distribution, and tax progressivity in a search model
- Housing market and labor market search
- Rented vs. owner-occupied housing and monetary policy
- On the cyclicality of real wages and wage differentials
- Aggregate implications of occupational inheritance in China and India
- Barriers to firm growth in open economies
- The role of IPRs on prices, wages and growth in a two country directed technical change model
- Fiscal counter-cyclicality and productive investment: evidence from advanced economies
- Contributions
- Is risk shock a key factor driving business cycles in China?
- Did capital replace labor? New evidence from offshoring
- International capital mobility and structural transformation
- Redistributive policies and technology diffusion
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontiers
- The Precautionary Saving Effect of Government Consumption
- Advanced
- Optimal taxation under equilibrium unemployment and economic profits
- Labor supply, income distribution, and tax progressivity in a search model
- Housing market and labor market search
- Rented vs. owner-occupied housing and monetary policy
- On the cyclicality of real wages and wage differentials
- Aggregate implications of occupational inheritance in China and India
- Barriers to firm growth in open economies
- The role of IPRs on prices, wages and growth in a two country directed technical change model
- Fiscal counter-cyclicality and productive investment: evidence from advanced economies
- Contributions
- Is risk shock a key factor driving business cycles in China?
- Did capital replace labor? New evidence from offshoring
- International capital mobility and structural transformation
- Redistributive policies and technology diffusion