Home Asymmetric Performance Evaluation Under Quantity and Price Competition with Managerial Delegation
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Asymmetric Performance Evaluation Under Quantity and Price Competition with Managerial Delegation

  • Jumpei Hamamura ORCID logo and Vinay Ramani EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: April 16, 2024

Abstract

In this paper, we consider asymmetric performance evaluation contracts under different product market configurations with managerial delegation and specify the optimal decision-making by the social and relative performance evaluation firms. We present a reversal result on the owner’s choice of the social performance and relative performance evaluation contract as the product market competition type changes from quantity to price competition. Surprisingly, results indicate that the consumer surplus increases as the degree of product substitution increases under quantity competition in a specific economic environment. A firm that considers social performance evaluation produces less, charges a higher price, and earns a lower profit than a firm that uses relative performance evaluation. We also endogenize the choice of performance evaluation systems. While relative performance emerges as the endogenous choice under both modes of product market competition, it leads to lower consumer surplus and social welfare in comparison to an asymmetric performance evaluation system.


Corresponding author: Vinay Ramani, Department of Industrial & Management Engineering, Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur, 208016, India, E-mail:

Award Identifier / Grant number: JP21K13409

Award Identifier / Grant number: The Japanese Association of Management Accounting

Acknowledgments

We would like to sincerely thank two anonymous referees and the editor, Prof. Till Requate for their helpful comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this paper. Any remaining errors are our responsibility.

  1. Research funding: This work was partially supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number JP21K13409, and The Japanese Association of Management Accounting (Study Group in 2022).

Appendix A: Additional Analysis: Firm 1 Emphasizes Social Welfare

To check the robustness of our results, in this appendix, we analyze the case in which the objective function of Firm 1’s (social performance firm) manager considers social welfare. The objective function of Firm 2 remains the same as in the main model, i.e. V 2 = π 2 + α 2 π 1. Several earlier social corporate responsibility or mixed oligopoly studies which consider socially concerned firms examine the effect of emphasizing social welfare on the decision-making and profits (e.g. Hino and Zennyo 2017; Liu, Wang, and Chen 2018; Matsumura 1998; Matsumura and Ogawa 2014; Nakamura 2018; Pal 1998). We aim to understand whether the findings reported in our main analysis with consumer surplus as the social performance measure continue to hold with social welfare applied as the social performance measure.

Quantity Competition

First, we consider the case of quantity competition wherein the objective function of Firm 1’s manager considers social welfare: i.e. V 1 = π 1 + α 1 SW. By backward induction, we specify outcomes in this case and obtain the Outcome 3 in Appendix B.

In this analysis, the rival’s profit is included in the objective function of Firm 1. Therefore, our additional analysis yields different outcomes compared to Outcome 1 in Appendix B. However, comparing the effect of emphasizing the rival’s profit (reducing quantity) with the effect of emphasizing consumer surplus (increasing quantity), the latter effect is important. Therefore, the effects of θ on strategies have only a few differences between the main and additional models. Figure A.1 presents the effects of θ on α i Ccs and α i Csw where the superscript Csw denotes quantity (Cournot) competition with social welfare as the objective. From this figure, the inflection point remains largely unchanged.

Figure A.1: 
Relation between 




α


i


Ccs




${\alpha }_{i}^{\mathit{Ccs}}$



 and 




α


i


Csw




${\alpha }_{i}^{\mathit{Csw}}$



 under a = 1.
Figure A.1:

Relation between α i Ccs and α i Csw under a = 1.

In addition, based on Figure A.1, one can consider the relation between α i Ccs and α i Csw . We formalize the result in the following proposition.

Proposition A.1.

The weight assigned to social welfare by Firm 1 in the quantity competition case, α 1 Csw , always exceeds the weight placed on consumer surplus by Firm 1 in the quantity competition case, α 1 Ccs . In addition, for Firm 2, the weight it places on the rival firm’s profit is greater when Firm 1 considers CS as the objective compared to when it considers SW. Formally, α 1 Csw > α 1 Ccs and α 2 Csw < α 2 Ccs are always satisfied.

Proof.

The proof is presented in Appendix D.

Again, Figure A.1 presents the relation between α i Ccs and α i Csw in this case. From this figure, one can confirm that α 1 Csw > α 1 Ccs and α 2 Csw < α 2 Ccs is always satisfied. Therefore, π 2, which is included in SW, has a negligible effect on the decision-making of the socially concerned firm under quantity competition. In this case, because social welfare includes the rival’s profit and consumer surplus, the weight placed on the rival’s profit is important in committing to an aggressive strategy in product market competition. Therefore, Firm 1 can increase quantity using a more aggressive (large) α 1 to obtain a significant market share in the product market. This effect leads to a large α 1 to threaten the rival.

Price Competition

Next, we consider the case of price competition wherein the objective function of Firm 1’s manager considers social welfare: i.e. V 1 = π 1 + α 1 SW. In this case, the objective function of Firm 2 stays the same. We are interested in confirming whether the results obtained under price competition remain the same when Firm 1 considers social welfare as the objective instead of consumer surplus. The equilibrium solutions of this model are reported as Outcome 4 in Appendix B. Here, the superscript Bsw denotes price (Bertrand) competition with social welfare as the objective. Furthermore, α 1 Bsw < 0 for all θ ∈ (0, 1] and α 2 Bsw > 0 for 0 < θ ( 17 1 ) / 4 .

Comparing the optimal solutions of Firm 1 and Firm 2, we can infer that p 1 Bsw > p 2 Bsw , q 1 Bsw < q 2 Bsw and π 1 Bsw < π 2 Bsw , which is identical to the case in which Firm 1 considers weight on consumer surplus. Next, consumer surplus and social welfare are obtained as follows.

C S Bsw = a 2 [ 16 4 A Bsw θ ( 32 6 A Bsw ) θ 2 ( 28 10 A Bsw ) + θ 3 ( 76 + 58 θ θ 3 + A Bsw ) ] 64 θ 2 ( 1 + θ ) 2 , S W Bsw = a 2 [ 16 + 4 A Bsw + 2 θ A Bsw + θ 2 ( 76 2 A Bsw ) + θ 3 ( 68 2 θ θ 2 ( 8 θ ) A Bsw ) ] 64 θ 2 ( 1 + θ ) 2 .

Proposition A.2.

The weight placed on social welfare by Firm 1 in the price competition case, α 1 Bsw , is always lower than the weight placed on consumer surplus by Firm 1 in the price competition case. In addition, for Firm 2, the weight it places on Firm 1’s profit is lower when Firm 1 considers SW compared to the case in which Firm 1 considers CS. Formally, α 1 Bsw < α 1 Bcs and α 2 Bsw < α 2 Bcs are always satisfied.

Proof.

The proof is presented in Appendix D.

Comparison of the weights between the two models presents an interesting reversal result. Although Firm 1 attaches a higher weight to social welfare than consumer surplus under quantity competition, it assigns a lower weight to social welfare than consumer surplus under price competition. For Firm 2, the weights under social welfare are lower than that under consumer surplus. The intuition for the result is the following. Social welfare includes consumer surplus and the profits of both Firm 1 and Firm 2. Under price competition, Firm 1 adopts a less aggressive strategy under the social welfare objective than the consumer surplus objective. As a result, Firm 2 also chooses a lower α 2 when Firm 1 assigns weight to social welfare.

Figure A.2 depicts the comparison pictorially. It is particularly interesting that α 2 BSw is non-monotonically increasing as θ increases. A higher θ implies that goods are close substitutes, intensifying the price competition. This increases the consumer surplus. As a result, Firm 1 assigns a higher weight in the case of consumer surplus, as opposed to social welfare. Consequently, Firm 2 also increases the weight on Firm 1’s profit in the case of consumer surplus.

Figure A.2: 
Relation between 




α


i


Bcs




${\alpha }_{i}^{\mathit{Bcs}}$



 and 




α


i


Bsw




${\alpha }_{i}^{\mathit{Bsw}}$



 under a = 1 for i = 1, 2.
Figure A.2:

Relation between α i Bcs and α i Bsw under a = 1 for i = 1, 2.

Finally, we can observe from the optimal solutions that 1 Bsw / θ < 0 for all θ ∈ (0, 1] and 2 Bsw / θ > 0 for 0 < θ < 0.524 and 2 Bsw / θ < 0 for 0.524 < θ < 1. In addition, consumer surplus is increasing in the degree of product substitution: ∂CS Bsw /∂θ > 0 for all θ ∈ (0, 1].

Appendix B: Outcomes

In Appendix B, we label the outcomes as Outcome to refer in our manuscript. All analysis are provided in Appendix D Additionally, A Ccs , B Ccs , A Bcs , A Csw , and A Bsw are defined in Appendix C.

Outcome 1.

Under the quantity competition, the optimal quantities chosen by the two firms, prices, and profits are, respectively

q 1 Ccs = a 12 4 θ 5 θ 2 2 θ 3 8 A Ccs 4 θ 8 θ 2 2 θ 3 θ 4 8 1 θ 1 + θ 2 A Ccs + 8 A Ccs 4 θ 16 θ 2 θ 3 θ 4 , q 2 Ccs = a 8 A Ccs 4 + 4 3 A Ccs + 8 θ 2 7 A Ccs 16 θ 2 5 A Ccs + 56 θ 3 + 22 θ 4 + 4 θ 5 3 θ 6 8 θ 1 θ 1 + θ 2 A Ccs + 8 A Ccs 4 θ 16 θ 2 θ 3 θ 4 , p 1 Ccs = a ( 2 θ ) 4 , p 2 Ccs = a 8 4 A Ccs + 4 A Ccs + 24 θ 2 A Ccs + 32 θ 2 + 5 A Ccs 24 θ 3 + 2 A Ccs + 13 θ 4 + 24 θ 5 + 9 θ 6 + 2 θ 7 8 θ 2 A Ccs + 8 A Ccs 4 θ 16 θ 2 θ 3 θ 4 , π 1 Ccs = a 2 ( 2 θ ) 12 4 θ 5 θ 2 2 θ 3 8 A Ccs 4 θ 8 θ 2 2 θ 3 θ 4 32 1 θ 1 + θ 2 A Ccs + 8 A Ccs 4 θ 16 θ 2 θ 3 θ 4 , π 2 Ccs = a 2 B Ccs 8 A Ccs 4 + 4 3 A Ccs + 8 θ 2 7 A Ccs 16 θ 2 5 A Ccs + 56 θ 3 + 22 θ 4 + 4 θ 5 3 θ 6 64 θ 2 1 θ 1 + θ 2 A Ccs + 8 A Ccs 4 θ 16 θ 2 θ 3 θ 4 2 .

Outcome 2.

Under the price competition, the optimal prices charged by the two firms, the optimal quantities, and profits are, respectively,

p 1 Bcs = a ( θ 3 + A Bcs ) 8 ( 1 + θ ) , p 2 Bcs = a ( A Bcs 4 + 2 θ + 4 θ 2 θ 3 ) 8 θ ( 1 + θ ) , q 1 Bcs = a ( 2 + θ ) 4 ( 1 + θ ) , q 2 Bcs = a ( 4 + 6 θ θ 3 A Bcs ) 8 θ ( 1 + θ ) , π 1 Bcs = a 2 ( 2 + θ ) ( θ 3 + A Bcs ) 32 ( 1 + θ ) 2 , π 2 Bcs = a 2 ( 2 θ ) A Bcs 8 + 10 θ 2 θ 4 16 θ 2 ( 1 + θ ) .

Outcome 3.

When the socially concerned firm emphasizes social welfare, under the quantity competition, the optimal weights chosen by the two firms, quantity, prices, and profits are, respectively

α 1 Csw = A Csw 4 + 2 θ + 4 θ 2 + 3 θ 3 2 2 θ 2 θ 2 + θ 3 , α 2 Csw = A Csw 4 + 2 θ + 2 θ 2 ( 2 θ ) θ 2 , q 1 Csw = a A Csw θ 3 8 1 θ 2 , q 2 Csw = a A Csw 4 2 θ + 4 θ 2 + θ 3 8 θ θ 2 1 , p 1 Csw = a ( 2 θ ) 4 , p 2 Csw = a A Csw 4 + 6 θ θ 3 8 θ , π 1 Csw = a 2 ( 2 θ ) A Csw θ 3 32 1 θ 2 , π 2 Csw = a 2 A Csw 4 + 6 θ θ 3 A Csw 4 2 θ + 4 θ 2 + θ 3 64 θ 2 θ 2 1 .

Outcome 4.

When the socially concerned firm emphasizes social welfare, under the price competition, the optimal weights chosen by the two firms, the equilibrium prices, quantities, and profit of the two firms are, respectively

α 1 Bsw = 4 θ 2 + θ ( 2 3 θ ) A Bsw 2 ( 2 θ ) ( 1 θ ) ( 1 + θ ) , α 2 Bsw = 8 ( 2 + θ ) A Bsw 2 θ 2 5 2 θ + θ 2 ( 2 θ ) θ 2 12 + 4 θ θ 2 ( 5 2 θ ) , p 1 Bsw = a 8 A Bsw θ 2 ( 6 θ ) 8 ( 1 + θ ) , p 2 Bsw = a 4 A Bsw + θ 2 θ ( 2 + θ ) 8 θ ( 1 + θ ) , q 1 Bsw = a ( 2 + θ ) 4 ( 1 + θ ) , q 2 Bsw = a A Bsw + 6 θ + θ 2 ( 6 θ ) 4 8 θ ( 1 + θ ) , π 1 Bsw = a 2 ( 2 + θ ) 8 A Bsw θ 2 ( 6 θ ) 64 θ 2 ( 1 + θ ) 2 , π 2 Bsw = a 2 A Bsw + 6 θ + θ 2 ( 6 θ ) 4 4 + 2 θ θ 2 ( 2 + θ ) A Bsw 64 θ 2 ( 1 + θ ) 2 .

Appendix C: Definitions

Appendix C shows definitions of the replaced variables in our analysis. In Section 5, the following variables are used.

A Ccs θ 6 + 4 θ 5 + 16 θ 4 24 θ 3 28 θ 2 + 16 θ + 16 , B Ccs 2 θ 7 + 9 θ 6 + 24 θ 5 + 2 A Ccs + 13 θ 4 + 5 A Ccs 24 θ 3 2 A Ccs + 32 θ 2 + 4 A Ccs + 24 θ 8 A Ccs 4 , C Ccs 4 θ 14 + 20 θ 13 + 85 θ 12 4 ( 159 A Ccs + 2888 ) θ 6 8 ( 19 A Ccs 80 ) θ 5 + 16 ( 137 A Ccs + 720 ) θ 4 32 ( A Ccs 32 ) θ 3 64 ( 25 A Ccs + 32 ) θ 2 + 128 ( A Ccs 8 ) θ + 256 ( A Ccs 4 ) + 4 ( A Ccs + 22 ) θ 11 + 6 ( 2 A Ccs + 7 ) θ 10 + ( 37 A Ccs + 908 ) θ 9 + ( 30 A Ccs + 2212 ) θ 8 14 ( 17 A Ccs + 64 ) θ 7 , D Ccs 4 θ 14 + 12 θ 13 + 75 θ 12 20 ( 29 A Ccs + 1416 ) θ 6 8 ( 649 A Ccs + 512 ) θ 5 + 48 ( 85 A Ccs + 864 ) θ 4 + 32 ( 133 A Ccs 176 ) θ 3 64 ( 39 A Ccs + 272 ) θ 2 128 ( 5 A Ccs 24 ) θ 256 ( A Ccs 4 ) 4 ( A Ccs 164 ) θ 11 + ( 20 A Ccs + 718 ) θ 10 + ( 59 A Ccs 92 ) θ 9 + 6 ( 55 A Ccs 142 ) θ 8 + ( 422 A Ccs + 9376 ) θ 7 .

Under 0.45 < θ < 1, A Ccs < 4 is satisfied.

In Section 6, the following variable is used.

A Bcs 16 + 16 θ 12 θ 2 16 θ 3 4 θ 4 + θ 6 .

In Section A, the following variable is used.

A Csw θ 6 4 θ 4 + 16 θ 3 12 θ 2 16 θ + 16 .

In Section A, the following variables are used.

A Bsw 16 ( 1 θ ) 28 θ 2 + θ 3 24 + 16 θ θ 2 ( 4 θ ) .

Appendix D: Proofs

Analysis for Outcome 1

By backward induction, we can specify the optimal strategies and profits under quantity competition as Outcome 1. First, we consider the stage 2 problem for managers. In the quantity competition case, managers decide q 1 and q 2 to maximize V 1 = π 1 + α 1 CS and V 2 = π 2 + α 2 π 1. From the first-order conditions, we obtain the following Best-response functions of the stage-2 problem.

(D.1) q 1 ( q 2 ) = a ( 1 α 1 ) θ q 2 2 α 1 ,

(D.2) q 2 ( q 1 ) = a ( 1 + α 2 ) θ q 1 2 .

From Eqs. (D.1) and (D.2), an increase in the quantity of the rival firm j, causes firm i to decrease its quantity, indicating that quantities are strategic substitutes even when the objective of one firm moves away from considering relative profits. Solving Eqs. (D.1) and (D.2), we obtain stage 2 solutions.

(D.3) q 1 ( α 1 , α 2 ) = a ( 2 ( 1 α 1 ) θ ) 4 α 1 2 ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 ,

(D.4) q 2 ( α 1 , α 2 ) = a ( 2 α 1 α 2 θ θ ) 4 α 1 2 ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 .

Based on this outcome, we obtain the optimal solutions of weights. In stage 1, the owner of the firm 1 decides the weight placed on consumer surplus. The owner of the firm 2 decides the weight assigned to the rival firm’s profit. Using Outcome 1, we obtain Proposition 1 straightforwardly. □

Proof of Proposition 2

Considering α 1 Ccs / θ and α 2 Ccs / θ , we obtain

(D.5) α 1 Ccs θ = ( 2 2 θ 2 + θ θ 3 ) 2 4 θ 9 θ 2 3 θ 5 + 10 θ 4 + 32 θ 3 36 θ 2 28 θ + 8 A Ccs ( 1 4 θ ) ( 4 A Ccs + 2 θ 2 θ 2 3 θ 3 ) 2 ( 2 + θ 2 θ 2 θ 3 ) 2 ,

(D.6) α 2 Ccs θ = 2 A App θ 3 ( 2 θ 3 + 5 θ 2 + 4 θ 12 ) 2 A Ccs < 0 .

where A App ≡ − θ 10 − 2θ 9 − 10θ 8 + (A Ccs + 138)θ 7 + 2(8A Ccs + 75)θ 6 + 4(3A Ccs − 106)θ 5 + 2(A Ccs − 228)θ 4 + 4(A Ccs + 48)θ 3 − 80(A Ccs − 10)θ 2 − 48A Ccs θ + 96(A Ccs − 4). From the numerator of Eq. (D.5), under θ ̲ Ccs 0.796 < θ < 1 , α 1 Ccs / θ < 0 holds. □

Proof of Proposition 4

After considering q 1 Ccs q 2 Ccs , we obtain the following outcome:

(D.7) q 1 Ccs q 2 Ccs = a B App 8 ( 1 θ ) θ 2 A Ccs + 8 A Ccs 4 θ 16 θ 2 θ 3 θ 4 < 0 ,

where B App ≡ 8(A Ccs − 4) + 4(A Ccs − 8)θ − 6(A Ccs − 8)θ 2 − 3(A Ccs − 16)θ 3 − 2(A Ccs − 1)θ 4 − 26θ 5 − 7θ 6 − 2θ 7. □

Proof of Proposition 5

We consider ∂CS Ccs /∂θ and get the following outcome:

(D.8) C S Ccs θ = D App E App F App G App ,

where C App ≡ 6θ 5 + 20θ 4 + 64θ 3 − 72θ 2 − 56θ + 16, D App ( a 2 ( 56 θ 13 + 260 θ 12 + 2 C App θ 11 / A Ccs + 1020 θ 11 + 44 ( A Ccs + 22 ) θ 10 + 6 C App θ 10 / A Ccs + 60 ( 2 A Ccs + 7 ) θ 9 + 37 C App θ 9 / 2 A Ccs + 9 ( 37 A Ccs + 908 ) θ 8 + 15 C App θ 8 / A Ccs + 8 ( 30 A Ccs + 2212 ) θ 7 119 C App θ 7 / A Ccs 98 ( 17 A Ccs + 64 ) θ 6 318 C App θ 6 / A Ccs 24 ( 159 A Ccs + 2888 ) θ 5 76 C App θ 5 / A Ccs 40 ( 19 A Ccs 80 ) θ 4 + 1096 C App θ 4 / A Ccs + 64 ( 137 A Ccs + 720 ) θ 3 16 C App θ 3 / A Ccs 96 ( A Ccs 32 ) θ 2 800 C App θ 2 / A Ccs 128 ( 25 A Ccs + 32 ) θ + 64 C App θ / A Ccs + 128 ( A Ccs 8 ) + 128 C App / A Ccs ) ) / 64 θ 2 ( θ 2 1 ) ( θ 4 + θ 3 + 16 θ 2 + ( A Ccs 4 ) θ 2 ( A Ccs + 8 ) ) 2 , E App ( a 2 ( 4 θ 14 + 20 θ 13 + 85 θ 12 + 4 ( A Ccs + 22 ) θ 11 + 6 ( 2 A Ccs + 7 ) θ 10 + ( 37 A Ccs + 908 ) θ 9 + ( 30 A Ccs + 2212 ) θ 8 14 ( 17 A Ccs + 64 ) θ 7 4 ( 159 A Ccs + 2888 ) θ 6 8 ( 19 A Ccs 80 ) θ 5 + 16 ( 137 A Ccs + 720 ) θ 4 32 ( A Ccs 32 ) θ 3 64 ( 25 A Ccs + 32 ) θ 2 + 128 ( A Ccs 8 ) θ + 256 ( A Ccs 4 ) ) ) / ( 32 θ 3 ( θ 2 1 ) ( θ 4 + θ 3 + 16 θ 2 + ( A Ccs 4 ) θ 2 ( A Ccs + 8 ) ) 2 ) , and F App ( a 2 ( 4 θ 14 + 20 θ 13 + 85 θ 12 + 4 ( A Ccs + 22 ) θ 11 + 6 ( 2 A Ccs + 7 ) θ 10 + ( 37 A Ccs + 908 ) θ 9 + ( 30 A Ccs + 2212 ) θ 8 14 ( 17 A Ccs + 64 ) θ 7 4 ( 159 A Ccs + 2888 ) θ 6 8 ( 19 A Ccs 80 ) θ 5 + 16 ( 137 A Ccs + 720 ) θ 4 32 ( A Ccs 32 ) θ 3 64 ( 25 A Ccs + 32 ) θ 2 + 128 ( A Ccs 8 ) θ + 256 ( A Ccs 4 ) ) ) / ( 32 θ ( θ 2 1 ) 2 ( θ 4 + θ 3 + 16 θ 2 + ( A Ccs 4 ) θ 2 ( A Ccs + 8 ) ) 2 ) , and G App ( a 2 ( 4 θ 3 + 3 θ 2 + C App θ / 2 A Ccs + 32 θ + A Ccs C App / A Ccs 4 ) ( 4 θ 14 + 20 θ 13 + 85 θ 12 + 4 ( A Ccs + 22 ) θ 11 + 6 ( 2 A Ccs + 7 ) θ 10 + ( 37 A Ccs + 908 ) θ 9 + ( 30 A Ccs + 2212 ) θ 8 14 ( 17 A Ccs + 64 ) θ 7 4 ( 159 A Ccs + 2888 ) θ 6 8 ( 19 A Ccs 80 ) θ 5 + 16 ( 137 A Ccs + 720 ) θ 4 32 ( A Ccs 32 ) θ 3 64 ( 25 A Ccs + 32 ) θ 2 + 128 ( A Ccs 8 ) θ + 256 ( A Ccs 4 ) ) ) / ( 32 θ 2 ( θ 2 1 ) ( θ 4 + θ 3 + 16 θ 2 + ( A Ccs 4 ) θ 2 ( A Ccs + 8 ) ) 3 ) . Under 0 < θ < 0.966 θ ̄ , ∂CS Ccs /∂θ > 0 holds.

Additionally, we demonstrate the existence of the inflection point. It is larger than θ = 0.966 using numerical examples. Under a = 1, when θ = 0.966, ∂CS/∂θ = 0.000641386 > 0 is obtained. However, θ = 0.967, ∂CS/∂θ = −0.000427304 < 0 is obtained. Therefore, the inflection point exists in 0.966 < θ < 0.967. Because the existence of positive ∂CS/∂θ in this proposition is important, we propose our important results obtained using numerical examples. From the discussion presented above, under a = 1, when θ = 0.966, ∂CS/∂θ = 0.000641386 > 0 is obtained. In addition, when θ = 0.01, ∂CS/∂θ = 0.00124063 is obtained. From the discussion presented above, there exists θ ( 0 , θ ̄ ) such that ∂CS/∂θ > 0.

Figure D.1 presents the effect of θ on ∂CS Ccs /∂θ under a = 1. From this figure, one can confirm that there exists a case of ∂CS Ccs /∂θ > 0.□

Figure D.1: 
Effect of θ on ∂CS

Ccs
/∂θ under a = 1.
Figure D.1:

Effect of θ on ∂CS Ccs /∂θ under a = 1.

Proof of Proposition 6

Solving Eqs. (D.21) and (D.22), we get the optimal contract weights as α 1 Bcs = ( A Bcs 4 2 θ + 4 θ 2 + 3 θ 3 ) / 2 ( 2 + θ 2 θ 2 θ 3 ) and α 2 Bcs = ( 4 + 2 θ 2 θ 2 A Bcs ) / θ 2 ( 2 + θ ) .

To demonstrate that α 1 Bcs < 0 , it suffices to prove that the numerator expressions A Bcs − 4 − 2θ + 4θ 2 + 3θ 3 > 0. To illustrate this point, it is noteworthy that, on simplification, we obtain

(D.9) A Bcs 4 2 θ + 4 θ 2 + 3 θ 3 = 8 ( 2 θ 2 θ 4 ) + 24 θ ( 1 θ 2 ) > 0 .

Similarly, to prove that α 2 Bcs > 0 , it suffices to prove that the numerator expression 4 + 2θ − 2θ 2A Bcs > 0. Regarding this point on simplification, we obtain

(D.10) 4 + 2 θ 2 θ 2 A Bcs = θ 3 ( 8 θ 3 ) + 8 θ 4 > 0 .

This completes the proof. □

Proof of Proposition 7

From α 1 Bcs α 1 B B , we get

(D.11) α 1 Bcs α 1 B B = 2 ( 4 A Ccs ) + 4 θ + A Ccs 4 θ 2 6 θ 3 2 θ 4 + θ 5 2 ( θ 1 ) ( θ + 1 ) ( θ + 2 ) θ 2 2 > 0 .

This result implies α 1 Bcs > α 1 B B . □

Proof of Proposition 8

From the optimal solutions, we have

(D.12) α 1 Bcs θ = θ 16 9 θ 4 θ 5 θ 6 4 θ 2 22 θ 3 + 24 θ ( θ 2 3 θ + θ 3 ) A Bcs ( 1 θ ) 2 ( 1 + θ ) 2 ( 2 + θ ) 2 A Bcs < 0 ,

(D.13) α 2 Bcs θ = 2 32 8 A Bcs + 2 θ 2 ( 4 A Bcs ) + 8 θ ( 6 A Bcs ) θ 3 ( 20 A Bcs ) 12 θ 4 2 θ 5 θ 6 θ 3 ( 2 + θ ) 2 A Bcs > 0 .

This completes the proof. □

Analysis for Outcome 2

We begin with the stage-2 problem for managers whereby the manager of Firm 1 chooses p 1 to maximize V 1 = π 1 + α 1 CS. The manager of Firm 2 chooses p 2 to maximize V 2 = π 2 + α 2 π 1. Differentiating the objective functions of the managers, we have

(D.14) V 1 p 1 = ( 1 α 1 ) a ( 1 θ ) + θ p 2 ( 2 α 1 ) p 1 1 θ 2 = 0 ,

(D.15) V 2 p 2 = a ( 1 θ ) + θ ( 1 + α 2 ) p 1 1 θ 2 = 0 ,

yielding the reaction functions

(D.16) p 1 ( p 2 ) = ( 1 α 1 ) ( 1 θ ) a + θ p 2 2 α 1 , p 2 ( p 1 ) = 1 2 ( 1 θ ) a + θ ( 1 + α 2 ) p 1 .

The second-order conditions are satisfied as V 1 2 / p 1 2 = ( 2 α 1 ) / ( 1 θ 2 ) < 0 and V 2 2 / p 2 2 = 2 / ( 1 θ 2 ) < 0 . The Best-response functions of the stage-two problem are, respectively,

(D.17) p 1 ( p 2 ) = ( 1 α 1 ) ( 1 θ ) a + θ p 2 2 α 1 ,

(D.18) p 2 ( p 1 ) = 1 2 ( 1 θ ) a + θ ( 1 + α 2 ) p 1 .

From Eqs. (D.17) and (D.18), we can infer that an increase in the price of the rival firm j causes firm i to increase its price, indicating that prices are strategic complements even when the objective of one firm moves away from considering relative profits. Solving Eqs. (D.17) and (D.18), we obtain the stage 2 solutions as

(D.19) p 1 ( α 1 , α 2 ) = a ( 1 α 1 ) ( 1 θ ) ( 2 + θ ) 4 2 α 1 ( 1 α 1 ) ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 ,

(D.20) p 2 ( α 1 , α 2 ) = a ( 1 θ ) 2 α 1 + ( 1 α 1 ) ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 4 2 α 1 ( 1 α 1 ) ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 .

We solve the stage 1 problem for the owners. Notably, each owner chooses the contract weight α i to maximize profits. Substituting Eqs. (D.19) and (D.20) into the profits, and taking the derivative with respect to the weights, we have the stage 1 best-response functions as

(D.21) α 1 ( α 2 ) = ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 2 ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 ,

(D.22) α 2 ( α 1 ) = θ 2 + θ ( 1 + θ ) α 1 4 + ( 2 θ ) θ ( 1 + θ ) α 1 .

Solving Eqs. (D.21) and (D.22), we obtain the optimal solutions for the weights. Proposition 6 formalizes the result. Substituting the reaction functions given in Eq. (D.16), we get the stage 1 profit functions of the owners as π 1(α 1, α 2) and π 2(α 1, α 2). Differentiating the objective functions of the two firms with respect to α 1 and α 2, we have the following reaction functions:

(D.23) α 1 ( α 2 ) = ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 2 ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 , α 2 ( α 1 ) = θ 2 + θ ( 1 + θ ) α 1 4 + ( 2 θ ) θ ( 1 + θ ) α 1 .

From Eq. (D.23), we get the optimal solutions α 1 Bcs and α 2 Bcs as given in Proposition 6. Substituting the optimal solutions in Eq. (D.16), the demand functions as well as the profit functions, we get the optimal solutions as given by Outcome 2. □

Proof of Proposition 9

Comparing the optimal prices charged by the two firms, we have the following on simplifying the expressions:

(D.24) p 1 Bcs p 2 Bcs = 4 a θ 4 ( 1 θ ) ( 1 θ 2 ) 8 θ ( 1 + θ ) > 0 .

Comparing the profit of the two firms, we have the following on simplifying the expressions: π 1 Bcs π 2 Bcs = ( A Bcs ( 2 ( 1 + θ ) ( 2 θ ) θ 2 ( 2 + θ ) ) + 2 ( 1 + θ ) ( 8 10 θ 2 + θ 4 ) + θ 5 ( 2 + θ ) ) / 32 θ 2 ( 1 + θ ) 2 < 0 for all θ ∈ (0, 1]. Therefore, π 1 Bcs < π 2 Bcs . □

Analysis for Outcome 3

By backward induction, we specify the optimal strategies in equilibrium. First, we consider stage-2. In this stage, managers decide supplied quantities to maximize their objective functions. Therefore, both firms face following maximization problems.

(D.25) max q 1 V 1 = max q 1 π 1 + α 1 S W ,

(D.26) max q 2 V 2 = max q 2 π 2 + α 2 π 2 .

From these maximization problems, we obtain the following Best-response functions.

(D.27) q 1 ( q 2 ) = ( α 1 + 1 ) ( a θ q 2 ) α 1 + 2 ,

(D.28) q 2 ( q 1 ) = a ( α 2 + 1 ) θ q 1 2 .

From Eqs. (D.27) and (D.28), we get following strategies in stage-2.

(D.29) q 1 = a ( α 1 + 1 ) ( 2 θ ) 4 α 1 2 ( α 2 + 1 ) θ 2 ( α 2 + 1 ) θ 2 ,

(D.30) q 2 = a ( 2 α 1 ( α 2 θ + θ 1 ) ( α 2 + 1 ) θ ) 4 α 1 2 ( α 2 + 1 ) θ 2 ( α 2 + 1 ) θ 2 .

Next, we analyze stage-1. In this stage, owners choose α i to maximize their own profits. Using outcomes found earlier, the owners face the following maximization problems.

(D.31) max α i π i ( α 1 , α 2 ) .

Solving the first-order conditions of both firms, we obtain α i Csw . In addition, using α i Csw , we get outcomes in Outcome 3. □

Proof of Proposition A.1

To demonstrate Proposition A.1, we consider α i Ccs α i Csw .

(D.32) α 1 Ccs α 1 Csw = 1 2 A Ccs 4 2 θ + 2 θ 2 + 3 θ 3 2 + θ 2 θ 2 θ 3 + A Csw 4 + 2 θ + 4 θ 2 3 θ 3 2 θ 2 θ 2 + θ 3 < 0 ,

(D.33) α 2 Ccs α 2 Csw = 1 θ 2 8 A Ccs ( 2 θ ) 10 θ 2 4 θ 3 + 4 θ 4 + 2 θ 5 12 4 θ 5 θ 2 2 θ 3 + A Csw 4 + 2 θ + 2 θ 2 2 θ > 0 .

Analysis for Outcome 4

Differentiating the objective functions of the managers, we have

(D.34) V 1 p 1 = a ( 1 θ ) ( 2 + α 1 ) p 1 θ ( 1 + α 1 ) p 2 1 θ 2 = 0 ,

(D.35) V 2 p 2 = a ( 1 θ ) + θ ( 1 + α 2 ) p 1 2 p 2 1 θ 2 = 0 ,

yielding the reaction functions

(D.36) p 1 ( p 2 ) = a ( 1 θ ) + θ ( 1 + α 1 ) p 2 2 + α 1 , p 2 ( p 1 ) = 1 2 a ( 1 θ ) + θ ( 1 + α 2 ) p 1 .

It is noteworthy that the second-order conditions are satisfied as V 1 2 / p 1 2 = ( 2 + α 1 ) / ( 1 θ 2 ) < 0 and V 2 2 / p 2 2 = 2 / ( 1 θ 2 ) < 0 . Substituting the reaction functions given in Eq. (D.36), we get the stage 1 profit functions of the owners as π 1(α 1, α 2) and π 2(α 1, α 2). Differentiating the objective functions of the two firms with respect to α 1 and α 2, we have the following reaction functions

(D.37) α 1 ( α 2 ) = ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 ( 2 + θ ) ( 2 θ ) 2 ( 1 + α 2 ) θ 2 , α 2 ( α 1 ) = θ ( 1 + α 1 ) ( 2 + θ + α 1 ) ( 2 + α 1 ) 2 + θ ( 1 + α 1 ) θ 2 ( 1 + α 1 ) .

From Eq. (D.37), we get the optimal solutions α 1 Bsw and α 2 Bsw as given in Outcome 4. Substituting the optimal solutions in Eq. (D.36), the demand functions as well as the profit functions, we obtain the optimal solutions as given in the Proposition. □

Analysis for Section 7.1

First, by backward induction, we can obtain the following outcomes straightforwardly.

α i RPEC = θ 2 + θ , π i RPEC = a 2 ( 2 θ ) ( 2 + θ ) 16 ( 1 + θ ) , C S RPEC = a 2 ( 2 + θ ) 2 16 ( 1 + θ ) , S W RPEC = a 2 12 + 4 θ θ 2 16 ( 1 + θ ) ,

where superscript RPEC denotes the case in which both firms adopt the RPE under quantity competition. Additionally, when both firms set consumer surplus as a performance indicator, we get the following outcomes.

α i CSC = 2 + 2 θ + θ 2 ψ 2 ( 1 + θ ) , π i CSC = 2 a 2 ψ θ ( 2 + θ ) ψ + 2 θ 2 2 , C S CSC = 4 a 2 ( 1 + θ ) ψ + 2 θ 2 2 , S W CSC = 4 a 2 ψ + 1 θ θ 2 ψ + 2 θ 2 2 ,

where superscript CSC denotes the case in which both firms adopt the social performance under quantity competition.[12] Additionally, ψ 4 + 8 θ + 4 θ 2 + θ 4 .

Based on the above result, we obtain.

α 2 RPEC α 2 Ccs = ( 2 θ ) 2 4 A Ccs + 8 A Ccs θ 6 θ 2 6 θ 3 3 θ 4 θ 2 ( θ + 2 ) 12 5 θ 2 4 θ 2 θ 3 > 0 , α 1 CSC α 1 Ccs = 2 ψ + θ θ 3 ψ θ ψ A Ccs 2 ( 1 + θ ) 2 θ θ 2 > 0 .

Next, we specify the equilibrium strategy in this case. Comparing the outcomes between this section and the previous section, we obtain the following outcomes.

π 1 RPEC π 1 Ccs = a 2 ( 2 θ ) θ ( θ 2 + 4 θ 2 ) + A Ccs 4 32 1 θ 2 > 0 , π 2 CSC π 2 Ccs = a 2 θ θ 2 ( 3 θ ) ψ + 2 θ 3 + 3 θ 3 + 2 ( 1 θ A Ccs ) + A Ccs + 2 ( A Ccs 2 ψ ) 16 θ 2 1 θ 2 < 0 .

Under the small θ, A Ccs > 4 is obtained, and θ(θ 2 + 4θ − 2) + A Ccs − 4 > 0. On the other hand, under the large θ, we can get the large value in θ 2 + 4θ − 2, and therefore θ(θ 2 + 4θ − 2) + A Ccs − 4 > 0 is satisfied. Because we suppose the symmetric profit functions, we can confirm the optimal choice of the performance indicator by considering this comparison. We can confirm the following two facts from this analysis. First, when the rival uses the RPE, the firm can enhance the profit by the RPE as a performance evaluation system. Second, when the rival uses social performance, the firm can enhance the profit by the RPE as a performance evaluation system. This analysis implies that if the firm can choose the performance indicator, then both firms set the RPE as a performance evaluation system in the equilibrium under quantity competition. This outcome leads to Proposition 10.

Lastly, we consider the welfare effect of endogenous choice of performance evaluation systems. To analyze the welfare effect, we compare the asymmetric case with the outcome under the optimal choice in equilibrium.

C S Ccs C S RPEC = a 2 4 A Ccs 4 + θ θ 2 A Ccs + θ θ ( θ ( θ + 4 ) 14 ) + A Ccs 4 + 28 2 A Ccs 64 θ 2 θ 2 1 > 0 , S W Ccs S W RPEC = a 2 4 A Ccs 4 + θ 6 A Ccs + θ 10 A Ccs + θ θ ( ( θ 4 ) θ 38 ) + A Ccs + 44 + 44 32 64 θ 2 θ 2 1 > 0 .

This result leads to Proposition 11.

Analysis for Section 7.2

By backward induction, we obtain the following profits for firm i, consumer surplus, and social welfare under both cases as follows.

α i RPEB = θ 2 θ , π i PREB = a 2 ( 2 θ ) ( 2 + θ ) 16 ( 1 + θ ) , C S RPEB = a 2 ( 2 + θ ) 2 16 ( 1 + θ ) , S W RPEB = a 2 12 + 4 θ θ 2 16 ( 1 + θ ) ,

where superscript RPEB denotes the case in which both firms adopt the RPE under price competition. Additionally, when both firms set consumer surplus as a performance indicator, we get the following outcomes.

α i CSB = 1 θ 2 1 θ 2 1 θ 2 , π i CSB = a 2 1 θ 2 1 + θ + 1 θ 2 2 , C S CSB = a 2 2 1 + 1 θ 2 , S W CSB = a 2 1 + θ + 2 1 θ 2 1 + θ + 1 θ 2 2 ,

where superscript CSB indicates the case in which both firms adopt social performance as a performance indicator under price competition.[13]

Based on the above result, we obtain.

α 2 RPEB α 2 Bcs = 2 θ 2 + A Bcs 4 2 θ θ 2 ( 2 + θ ) + θ 2 θ > 0 , α 1 CSB α 1 Bcs = θ 3 + A Bcs 2 θ 1 θ 2 4 1 θ 2 2 ( 2 + θ ) 1 θ 2 > 0 .

Next, we specify the equilibrium strategy in this case. Comparing the outcomes between this section and the previous section, we obtain the following outcomes.

π 1 RPEB π 1 Bcs = a 2 ( 2 + θ ) 4 A Bcs + 2 θ 2 θ 2 θ 3 32 ( 1 + θ ) 2 > 0 , π 2 CSB π 2 Bcs = a 2 2 A Bcs θ θ 3 + A Bcs 2 θ 8 1 θ 2 16 θ 2 ( 1 + θ ) < 0 .

Because we suppose the symmetric profit functions, we can confirm the optimal choice of the performance indicator by considering this comparison. We can confirm the following two facts from this analysis. First, when the rival uses the RPE, the firm can enhance the profit by the RPE as a performance evaluation system. Second, when the rival uses social performance, the firm can enhance the profit by the RPE as a performance evaluation system. This analysis implies that if the firm can choose the performance indicator, then both firms set the RPE as a performance evaluation system in the equilibrium under quantity competition. This outcome leads to Proposition 12.

Lastly, we consider the welfare effect of endogenous choice of performance evaluation systems. To analyze the welfare effect, we compare the asymmetric case with the outcome under the optimal choice in equilibrium.

C S Bcs C S RPEB = a 2 4 4 A Bcs θ 6 8 θ 5 14 θ 4 4 + A Bcs θ 3 + 4 5 A Bcs θ 2 + 32 6 A Bcs θ 64 θ 2 ( θ + 1 ) 2 > 0 , S W Bcs S W RPEB = a 2 4 4 A Bcs θ 6 + 10 θ 4 4 + A Bcs θ 3 4 7 A Bcs θ 2 2 A Bcs θ 64 θ 2 ( θ + 1 ) 2 > 0 .

This result leads to Proposition 13.

Proof of Proposition A.2

Comparing the contract parameter chosen by Firm 1 under CS and SW, we have

α 1 Bcs α 1 Bsw = 16 2 ( A Bcs + A Bsw ) + θ ( A Bcs A Bsw ) 16 θ 2 + 2 θ 3 + 6 θ 4 2 ( 4 5 θ 2 + θ 4 ) > 0 ,

implying that α 1 Bcs > α 1 Bsw .

Similarly, comparing the contract parameter chosen by Firm 2 under CS and SW, we have

α 2 Bcs α 2 Bsw = 4 ( 8 3 A Bcs + A Bsw ) + 4 θ ( 8 A Bcs + A Bsw ) + 2 θ 4 4 θ 5 + 2 θ 6 2 θ 3 ( 4 + A Bcs ) θ 2 ( 16 5 A Bcs A Bsw ) θ 2 ( 2 + θ ) ( 12 + 4 θ 5 θ 2 + 2 θ 3 ) > 0 ,

implying that α 2 Bcs > α 2 Bsw . □

References

Aggarwal, R. K., and A. A. Samwick. 1999. “Executive Compensation, Strategic Competition, and Relative Performance Evaluation: Theory and Evidence.” The Journal of Finance 54 (6): 1999–2043. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00180.Search in Google Scholar

Bárcena-Ruiz, J. C. 2007. “Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Duopoly: Price Competition.” Journal of Economics 91 (3): 263–72. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-007-0255-5.Search in Google Scholar

Barros, F. 1995. “Incentive Schemes as Strategic Variables: An Application to a Mixed Duopoly.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 13 (3): 373–86. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-7187(94)00461-a.Search in Google Scholar

Buccella, D., L. Fanti, and L. Gori. 2022a. “Green Managerial Delegation Theory.” Environment and Development Economics 27 (3): 223–49. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1355770x21000206.Search in Google Scholar

Buccella, D., L. Fanti, and L. Gori. 2022b. “The R&D Investment Decision Game with Product Differentiation.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 23 (2): 601–37. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2021-0129.Search in Google Scholar

Buccella, D., L. Fanti, and L. Gori. 2023. “Environmental Delegation Versus Sales Delegation: A Game-Theoretic Analysis.” Environment and Development Economics: 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1355770x23000025.Search in Google Scholar

Cabral, L. M. 2017. Introduction to Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Chen, J., C. Sun, J. Liu, and Y. Huo. 2021. “The Optimal Level of Corporate Social Responsibility Based on the Duopoly Model.” Managerial and Decision Economics 42 (1): 177–84. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3222.Search in Google Scholar

Chirco, A., M. Scrimitore, and C. Colombo. 2011. “Competition and the Strategic Choice of Managerial Incentives: The Relative Performance Case.” Metroeconomica 62 (4): 533–47. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-999x.2011.04124.x.Search in Google Scholar

Chou, C.-H. 2023. “Managerial Delegation, Product R&D and Subsidies on R&D Investment Costs.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 23 (1): 55–78, https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2021-0402.Search in Google Scholar

De Fraja, G., and F. Delbono. 1989. “Alternative Strategies of a Public Enterprise in Oligopoly.” Oxford Economic Papers 41 (1): 302–11. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a041896.Search in Google Scholar

Dixit, A. 1979. “A Model of Duopoly Suggesting a Theory of Entry Barriers.” The Bell Journal of Economics 10 (1): 20–32. https://doi.org/10.2307/3003317.Search in Google Scholar

Fanti, L., and D. Buccella. 2017. “Corporate Social Responsibility, Profits and Welfare with Managerial Firms.” International Review of Economics 64 (4): 341–56. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-017-0276-5.Search in Google Scholar

Fanti, L., and D. Buccella. 2019. “Managerial Delegation Games and Corporate Social Responsibility.” Managerial and Decision Economics 40 (6): 610–22. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3031.Search in Google Scholar

Fershtman, C., and K. L. Judd. 1987. “Equilibrium Incentives in Oligopoly.” The American Economic Review 77 (5): 927–40.Search in Google Scholar

Fjell, K., and D. Pal. 1996. “A Mixed Oligopoly in the Presence of Foreign Private Firms.” Canadian Journal of Economics 29 (3): 737–43, https://doi.org/10.2307/136260.Search in Google Scholar

Fumas, V. S. 1992. “Relative Performance Evaluation of Management: The Effects on Industrial Competition and Risk Sharing.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 10 (3): 473–89. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-7187(92)90008-m.Search in Google Scholar

Garcia, A., M. Leal, and S.-H. Lee. 2020a. “Cooperation with a Multiproduct Corporation in a Strategic Managerial Delegation.” Managerial and Decision Economics 41 (1): 3–9. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3073.Search in Google Scholar

Garcia, A., M. Leal, and S.-H. Lee. 2020b. “Welfare-Improving Cooperation with a Consumer-Friendly Multiproduct Corporation.” Managerial and Decision Economics 41 (7): 1144–55. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3161.Search in Google Scholar

Garcia, A., M. Leal, and S.-H. Lee. 2021. “Competitive Csr in a Strategic Managerial Delegation Game with a Multiproduct Corporation.” International Review of Economics 68 (3): 301–30. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-021-00370-4.Search in Google Scholar

Hamamura, J. 2021a. “Disclosure Policy for Relative Performance Indicators Under Product Market Competition.” https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3779116.10.2139/ssrn.3779116Search in Google Scholar

Hamamura, J. 2021b. “What Level Do Disadvantaged Firms Weight Rivals’ Profits in Relative Performance Evaluations Under Quantity Competition?” Managerial and Decision Economics 42 (2): 493–501. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3249.Search in Google Scholar

Hamamura, J. 2022. “Weight Assigned to a Rival’s Profit by an Advantaged Firm in Relative Performance Evaluation with Cournot-Bertrand Competition.” Managerial and Decision Economics 43 (7): 2838–44. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3565.Search in Google Scholar

Hamamura, J. 2024a. “Does a Leading Indicator Related to a Customer Improve a Firm’s Profit?” The Japanese Accounting Review.10.11640/tjar.14.2024.01Search in Google Scholar

Hamamura, J. 2024b. “Weight Placed on the Rival’s Profit Under the Relative Performance Evaluation with Cournot-Bertrand Competition and Sequential Decision of the Weight.” Accounting Letters.Search in Google Scholar

Hamamura, J., and K. Inoue. 2023. “The Nail that Stands is Hammered Down: Using Financial Reporting Comparability to Set Peer Groups on Benchmarking for Managerial Compensation in Japan.” https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4398675.Search in Google Scholar

Hamamura, J., and V. Ramani. 2023. “Social Performance vs. Relative Performance Evaluation, Asymmetric Costs, and Quantity Competition Under Managerial Delegation.” Managerial and Decision Economics 44 (3): 1706–19. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3777.Search in Google Scholar

Hamilton, J. H., and S. M. Slutsky. 1990. “Endogenous Timing in Duopoly Games: Stackelberg or Cournot Equilibria.” Games and Economic Behavior 2 (1): 29–46. https://doi.org/10.1016/0899-8256(90)90012-j.Search in Google Scholar

Hattori, M., and Y. Tanaka. 2016. “Subsidy for New Technology Adoption in Duopoly with Differentiated Goods Under Absolute and Relative Profit Maximization.” Journal of Economics Library 3 (3): 411–28.Search in Google Scholar

Heywood, J. S., and G. Ye. 2009. “Delegation in a Mixed Oligopoly: The Case of Multiple Private Firms.” Managerial and Decision Economics 30 (2): 71–82. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1436.Search in Google Scholar

Hino, Y., and Y. Zennyo. 2017. “Corporate Social Responsibility and Strategic Relationships.” International Review of Economics 64 (3): 231–44. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-016-0267-y.Search in Google Scholar

Huang, Y.-M., Q.-X. Li, Y.-Y. Guo, and Y.-H. Zhang. 2020. “Research on a Cournot–Bertrand Game Model with Relative Profit Maximization.” Complexity 2020: 1–12, https://doi.org/10.1155/2020/2358125.Search in Google Scholar

Jansen, T., A. van Lier, and A. Van Witteloostuijn. 2009. “On the Impact of Managerial Bonus Systems on Firm Profit and Market Competition: The Cases of Pure Profit, Sales, Market Share and Relative Profits Compared.” Managerial and Decision Economics 30 (3): 141–53. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1437.Search in Google Scholar

Jian, M., and K.-W. Lee. 2015. “CEO Compensation and Corporate Social Responsibility.” Journal of Multinational Financial Management 29: 46–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.mulfin.2014.11.004.Search in Google Scholar

Kim, S.-L., S.-H. Lee, and T. Matsumura. 2019. “Corporate Social Responsibility and Privatization Policy in a Mixed Oligopoly.” Journal of Economics 128 (1): 67–89. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-018-00651-7.Search in Google Scholar

Kopel, M. 2015. “Price and Quantity Contracts in a Mixed Duopoly with a Socially Concerned Firm.” Managerial and Decision Economics 36 (8): 559–66. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.2707.Search in Google Scholar

Kopel, M., and B. Brand. 2012. “Socially Responsible Firms and Endogenous Choice of Strategic Incentives.” Economic Modelling 29 (3): 982–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2012.02.008.Search in Google Scholar

Kopel, M., and L. Lambertini. 2012. “On the (Non) Existence of a Price Equilibrium in Delegation Games with Relative Performance Compensation.” Quaderni DSE Working Paper.10.2139/ssrn.1988115Search in Google Scholar

Kopel, M., and E. M. Putz. 2021. “Why Socially Concerned Firms Use Low-Powered Managerial Incentives: A Complementary Explanation.” Economic Modelling 94: 473–82. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2020.11.002.Search in Google Scholar

Lambertini, L., and A. Tampieri. 2015. “Incentives, Performance and Desirability of Socially Responsible Firms in a Cournot Oligopoly.” Economic Modelling 50: 40–8. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2015.05.016.Search in Google Scholar

Leal, M., A. García, and S.-H. Lee. 2020. “Effects of Integration with a Consumer-Friendly Firm in a Cournot Duopoly.” Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 20 (3): 587–604. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-019-00320-5.Search in Google Scholar

Leal, M., A. Garcia, and S.-H. Lee. 2021. “Sequencing R&D Decisions with a Consumer-Friendly Firm and Spillovers.” The Japanese Economic Review 72 (2): 243–60. https://doi.org/10.1007/s42973-019-00028-5.Search in Google Scholar

Li, H., W. Zhou, A. Elsadany, and T. Chu. 2021. “Stability, Multi-Stability and Instability in Cournot Duopoly Game with Knowledge Spillover Effects and Relative Profit Maximization.” Chaos, Solitons & Fractals 146: 110936. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chaos.2021.110936.Search in Google Scholar

Liu, Q., L. F. Wang, and C. L. Chen. 2018. “CSR in an Oligopoly with Foreign Competition: Policy and Welfare Implications.” Economic Modelling 72: 1–7. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2018.01.002.Search in Google Scholar

Matsumura, T. 1998. “Partial Privatization in Mixed Duopoly.” Journal of Public Economics 70 (3): 473–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0047-2727(98)00051-6.Search in Google Scholar

Matsumura, T., and A. Ogawa. 2014. “Corporate Social Responsibility or Payoff Asymmetry? A Study of an Endogenous Timing Game.” Southern Economic Journal 81 (2): 457–73. https://doi.org/10.4284/0038-4038-2012.182.Search in Google Scholar

Matsumura, T., N. Matsushima, and S. Cato. 2013. “Competitiveness and R&D Competition Revisited.” Economic Modelling 31: 541–7. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2012.12.016.Search in Google Scholar

Matsushima, N., and T. Matsumura. 2003. “Mixed Oligopoly and Spatial Agglomeration.” Canadian Journal of Economics 36 (1): 62–87. https://doi.org/10.1111/1540-5982.00004.Search in Google Scholar

Miller, N. H., and A. I. Pazgal. 2001. “The Equivalence of Price and Quantity Competition with Delegation.” The RAND Journal of Economics 32 (2): 284–301. https://doi.org/10.2307/2696410.Search in Google Scholar

Miller, N. H., and A. I. Pazgal. 2002. “Relative Performance as a Strategic Commitment Mechanism.” Managerial and Decision Economics 23 (2): 51–68. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1045.Search in Google Scholar

Nabin, M. H., X. Nguyen, P. M. Sgro, and C.-C. Chao. 2014. “Strategic Quality Competition, Mixed Oligopoly and Privatization.” International Review of Economics & Finance 34: 142–50. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2014.08.002.Search in Google Scholar

Nakamura, Y. 2014. “Capacity Choice in a Duopoly with a Consumer-Friendly Firm and an Absolute Profit-Maximizing Firm.” International Review of Economics & Finance 34: 105–17. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2014.07.004.Search in Google Scholar

Nakamura, Y. 2015. “Endogenous Choice of Strategic Incentives in a Mixed Duopoly with a New Managerial Delegation Contract for the Public Firm.” International Review of Economics & Finance 35: 262–77. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2014.10.008.Search in Google Scholar

Nakamura, Y. 2018. “Endogenous Market Structures in the Presence of a Socially Responsible Firm.” Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 18 (3): 319–48. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-017-0262-3.Search in Google Scholar

Nam, J. 2020. “Financial Reporting Comparability and Accounting-Based Relative Performance Evaluation in the Design of CEO Cash Compensation Contracts.” The Accounting Review 95 (3): 343–70. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-52588.Search in Google Scholar

Pal, D. 1998. “Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly.” Economics Letters 61 (2): 181–5. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0165-1765(98)00115-3.Search in Google Scholar

Pal, R. 2015. “Cournot vs. Bertrand Under Relative Performance Delegation: Implications of Positive and Negative Network Externalities.” Mathematical Social Sciences 75: 94–101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2015.02.007.Search in Google Scholar

Pal, D., and M. D. White. 1998. “Mixed Oligopoly, Privatization, and Strategic Trade Policy.” Southern Economic Journal 65 (2): 264–81. https://doi.org/10.1002/j.2325-8012.1998.tb00149.x.Search in Google Scholar

Planer-Friedrich, L., and M. Sahm. 2021. “Strategic CSR in Asymmetric Cournot Duopoly.” Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 21 (1): 33–42. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-020-00335-3.Search in Google Scholar

Poyago-Theotoky, J., and S. K. Yong. 2019. “Managerial Delegation Contracts, “Green” R&D and Emissions Taxation.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 19 (2): 1–10. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2017-0128.Search in Google Scholar

Singh, N., and X. Vives. 1984. “Price and Quantity Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly.” The RAND Journal of Economics 15 (4): 546–54. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555525.Search in Google Scholar

Sklivas, S. D. 1987. “The Strategic Choice of Managerial Incentives.” The RAND Journal of Economics 18 (3): 452–8. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555609.Search in Google Scholar

Vickers, J. 1985. “Delegation and the Theory of the Firm.” The Economic Journal 95: 138–47. https://doi.org/10.2307/2232877.Search in Google Scholar

Vroom, G. 2006. “Organizational Design and the Intensity of Rivalry.” Management Science 52 (11): 1689–702. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1060.0586.Search in Google Scholar

Wang, L. F. S. 2020. “Relative Performance Versus Market Share Delegation in a Vertically Related Market.” Arthaniti: Journal of Economic Theory and Practice 19 (1): 16–27. https://doi.org/10.1177/0976747919834740.Search in Google Scholar

White, M. D. 2001. “Managerial Incentives and the Decision to Hire Managers in Markets with Public and Private Firms.” European Journal of Political Economy 17 (4): 877–96. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0176-2680(01)00060-x.Search in Google Scholar

Xu, L., and S.-H. Lee. 2022. “Corporate Profit Tax and Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility under Foreign Acquisition.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 22 (1): 123–51.10.1515/bejte-2020-0028Search in Google Scholar

Xu, L., and T. Matsumura. 2022. “Welfare-Reducing Price Competition under Relative Performance Delegation with Convex Costs.” Economic Modelling 112: 105871. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105871.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2023-04-28
Accepted: 2024-03-07
Published Online: 2024-04-16

© 2024 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 19.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2023-0135/html
Scroll to top button