Home Global Warming and Border Carbon Adjustments
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Global Warming and Border Carbon Adjustments

  • Sungwan Hong , Seung-Gyu Sim ORCID logo , Ayako Obashi EMAIL logo and Yoshitaka Tsuruta
Published/Copyright: July 4, 2022
Become an author with De Gruyter Brill

Abstract

This study examines the welfare implications of allowing border carbon adjustments (BCAs) in a globalized economy characterized by international trade and cross-border pollution (CBP). The model predicts that adopting BCAs is a weakly dominant strategy and global welfare is maximized when at least one country adopts BCAs in the presence of CBP, such as global warming. This is because adopting BCAs induces other countries to raise their domestic emission tax rates without concerns such as the excessive shrinkage of domestic production and aggravation of CBP.

JEL Classification: H23; L51; Q56

Corresponding author: Ayako Obashi, Aoyama Gakuin University, 4-4-25 Shibuya, Shibuya-ku, Tokyo 150-8366, Japan, E-mail:

We thank Hsuan-Chih Lin and Soohyun Oh for initial motivation and encouragement. This work was partially supported by the Aoyama Gakuin University Research Institute. In addition, we thank Editage (www.editage.com) for English language editing.


Appendix A: Mathematical proofs

Proof of Lemma 1.

Summing up the first order conditions of home and foreign countries and reordering them yields

(A1) 0 = n [ 2 v ( q ) 2 c ( τ H + τ F ) γ ] + v ( q ) q [ v ( q ) q + ( 2 n + 1 ) v ( q ) ] d q d τ i = n γ .

Since v ( q ) q + ( 2 n + 1 ) v ( q ) < 0 , we know that d ( q H + q F ) / d τ i < 0 .

Taking derivative of (5) with respect to τ i and applying the symmetric condition ( q i = q i c = q ) yields

(A2) ( v ( q i ) c γ θ γ ) d ( q H + q F ) d τ i = 0 .

Since d ( q H + q F ) / d τ i 0 , we obtain that v ( q i ) = c + γ + θ γ for each i { H , F } . ∎

Proof of Lemma 2.

(i) Suppose to the contrary that q H is non-decreasing in τ H . Since ( q H + q F ) strictly decreases in τ H , q F should strictly decrease in τ H . Subtracting (7) from (8) and reordering implies that

(A3) v ( q ) ( q H q F ) = v ( q ) ( + ) ( q F q H ) = 2 n ( τ H τ F ) γ .

Equation (A3) implies that q H q F if and only if τ H τ F . It also implies that as τ H increases, ( 1 / 2 ) v ( q ) should increase, because ( q F q H ) strictly decreases in τ H . In addition, ( 1 / 2 ) v ( q ) q H should increase in τ H . Rewriting the first order conditions of each country and connecting them yields

(A4) 1 2 v ( q ) q H + n τ H γ = n [ v ( q ) c ] = 1 2 v ( q ) q F + n τ F γ .

It implies that as τ H increases unilaterally, 1 2 v ( q ) q H + n τ H should increase as much as 1 2 v ( q ) q F + n τ F does. However, since q F is decreasing in τ H but q H is nondecreasing, 1 2 v ( q ) q H + n τ H increases further than 1 2 v ( q ) q F , which is contradiction.

Therefore, q H should strictly decline with τ H . Differentiating foreign country’s first order condition with respect to τ H yields

(A5) 0 = [ 2 n v ( q ) + v ( q ) q F ] ( ) d q d τ H ( ) + v ( q ) ( ) d q F d τ H

Thus, we know that ( d q F ) / ( d τ H ) > 0 .

  1. By plugging ϕ H  = 0, differentiating (4) with respect to τ i , and simplifying yields

    (A6) 0 = ( v ( q ) c γ ) d q i d τ i θ γ d q i d τ i

    where i , i { H , F } and i i . ∎

Proof of Lemma 3.

Without loss of generality, assume that τ H > τ F . Summing up the first order conditions of foreign firms yields

(A7) q F d : 0 = n [ v ( q ) c τ F γ ] + 1 2 v ( q ) [ q F d + q F e ]   or   q F d = 0 ,  and
(A8) q F e : 0 = n [ v ( q ) c τ H γ ] + 1 2 v ( q ) [ q F d + q F e ]   or   q F e = 0 .

Suppose to the contrary that q F e 0 , which implies that q F e should solve for  n [ v ( q ) c τ H γ ] + [ q F d + q F e ] v ( q ) / 2 = 0 . Since τ F < τ H , n [ v ( q ) c τ F γ ] + [ q F d + q F e ] v ( q ) / 2 > 0 so that q F d = 0 . However, individual foreign firm j obtains larger profit by choosing ( q F j d + ϵ , q F j e ϵ ) for a sufficiently small ϵ > 0 without affecting the output price, because q F j d incurs less cost than q F j e . It’s contradiction. Therefore, we know that q F e = 0 .

Now, suppose to the contrary that q H e 0 . Summing up the first order conditions of home firms yields

(A9) q H e : 0 = n [ v ( q ) c τ H γ ] + 1 2 v ( q ) [ q H d + q H e ] ,   and
(A10) q H d : 0 = n [ v ( q ) c τ H γ ] + 1 2 v ( q ) [ q H d + q H e ]   or   q H d = 0 .

It implies that ( q F d + q F d ) solves for n [ v ( q ) c τ H γ ] + 1 2 v ( q ) [ q H d + q H e ] = 0 , whereas ( q F d + q F d ) solves for n [ v ( q ) c τ F γ ] + 1 2 v ( q ) [ q F d + q F e ] = 0 . Since q F e = 0 and τ H > τ F , we obtain that

(A11) q F d + q F e > q H d + q H e q F d > q H d + q H e q F d + q H e > q H d .

Then, it is a contradiction to p F = v ( q F d + q H e ) = v ( q H d ) = p H , that is, the output price in each country cannot be equal. Therefore, we conclude that q F e = q H e = 0 under mutual BCAs.

Finally, taking derivative of (4) with respect to τ i and applying q H e = ( d q H e / d τ i ) = q F e = ( d q F e / d τ i ) = 0 yields (14). ∎

Proof of Lemma 4.

First, consider the situation with τ H < τ F . Home country’s BCAs are not binding. It is same to the case of ‘No BCAs.’ Then, there is no mutual best response with τ H < τ F . Now, consider the situation with τ H τ F . Home country’s BCAs are binding. Then, it is same to the case of ‘Mutual BCAs.’ Therefore, the mutual best responses satisfy equation (14) as in Lemma 3. ∎

References

Bacchus, J. 2021. “Legal Issues with the European Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism.” Cato Briefing Paper, 125. Washington: Cato Institute. Available at https://www.cato.org/sites/cato.org/files/2021-08/briefing-paper-125.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Böhringer, C., E. Balistreri, and T. Rutherford. 2012. “The Role of Border Carbon Adjustment in Unilateral Climate Policy: Overview of an Energy Modeling Forum Study.” Energy Economics 34 (S2): S97–110, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2012.10.003.Search in Google Scholar

Cosbey, A., S. Droege, C. Fischer, and C. Munnings. 2019. “Developing Guidance for Implementing Border Carbon Adjustments: Lessons, Cautions, and Research Needs from the Literature.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 13 (1): 3–22, https://doi.org/10.1093/reep/rey020.Search in Google Scholar

Droege, S. 2011. “Using Border Measures to Address Carbon Flows.” Climate Policy 11 (5): 1191–201, https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2011.592671.Search in Google Scholar

Elliott, J., I. Foster, S. Kortum, M. Todd, F. Perez Cervantes, and D. Weisbach. 2010. “Trade and Carbon Taxes.” The American Economic Review 100 (2): 465–9, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.2.465.Search in Google Scholar

Jakob, M., R. Marschinski, and M. Hübler. 2013. “Between a Rock and a Hard Place: A Trade-Theory Analysis of Leakage under Production- and Consumption-Based Policies.” Environmental and Resource Economics 56: 47–72, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9638-y.Search in Google Scholar

Markusen, J. 1975. “International Externalities and Optimal Tax Structures.” Journal of International Economics 5: 15–29, https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(75)90025-2.Search in Google Scholar

Sim, S.-G., and H.-C. Lin. 2018. “Competitive Dominance of Emission Trading over Pigouvian Taxation in a Globalized Economy.” Economics Letters 163: 158–61, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2017.12.015.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2022-07-04

© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 8.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/ajle-2022-0033/html
Scroll to top button